Institutional Entrepreneurship in the Informal Economy: China's Shan‐Zhai Mobile Phones

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/sej.1174
AuthorShih‐Chang Hung,Chuan‐Kai Lee
Published date01 March 2014
Date01 March 2014
INSTITUTIONAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN THE
INFORMAL ECONOMY: CHINA’S SHAN-ZHAI
MOBILE PHONES
CHUAN-KAI LEE* and SHIH-CHANG HUNG
Institute of Technology Management, National Tsing Hua University, Taiwan
During the last decade, Chinese shan-zhai mobile phones have steadily and deliberately
evolved from an informal economy to a formal one. Wedraw on institutional entrepreneurship
to study this evolution, focusing in particular on how informal Chinese entrepreneurs pursued
change and the transition to a formal economy. We emphasize three strategies—framing,
aggregating, and bridging—Chinese entrepreneurs employed to mobilize support, garner
resources, and increase their amount and level of legitimacy. We also discuss implications
for research on informal economies and institutional entrepreneurship. Copyright © 2014
Strategic Management Society.
INTRODUCTION
Informal economies are pervasive, creative, and sig-
nificant to national development and entrepreneur-
ship. According to Godfrey (2011) and Webb et al.
(2013, among others, informal economic activity
accounts for as much as 10 to 20 percent of annual
gross domestic product in developed countries and
as much as 50 to 60 percent in developing countries.
Informal economies are often integrally bound up
with, and complementary to, the formal economy,
and they provide rich entrepreneurial opportunities
to new ventures. Despite a growing body of empiri-
cal studies and cases about informal economies
globally, little research exists on the informal
economy in China, a nation where a strong and
bureaucratized state, coupled with a large and
rapidly growing formal economy, has encouraged
legions of informal entrepreneurs to seek opportuni-
ties outside of state-sanctioned markets. To address
that gap in the literature, this study explores how
China’s shan-zhai1mobile phone sector developed
during the period 1998 to 2008. Success among
shan-zhai phones ultimately popularized ‘shan-zhai
methods of production for counterfeit, imitated, low-
cost, and do-it-yourself products in China and to ‘the
shan-zhai phenomena’ in general (Barboza, 2009;
Epstein, 2009).
Originally distributed within the stolen goods and
parallel imports markets, the shan-zhai mobile
phone sector began as a typical informal economy:
illegal and yet accepted by certain social groups
(Webb et al., 2009), especially those operating at the
bottom (or base) of the economic pyramid (BoP)
(London and Hart, 2011; Prahalad, 2005). Over the
last decade, this sector has evolved from being
scorned for its opportunism and inferiority to being
lauded as examples of entrepreneurship and innova-
tion. This happened in large part because shan-zhai
entrepreneurs actively contested the state’s ‘national
Keywords: informal economy; institutional entrepreneurship;
legitimacy-building strategies; Chinese mobile phones; case
study
*Correspondence to: Chuan-Kai Lee, Institute of Technology
Management, National Tsing Hua University, 101, Section 2,
Kuang-Fu Road, Hsinchu 30013, Taiwan. E-mail: cklee@
mx.nthu.edu.tw
1Shan-zhai—literally mountain (shan) fortress (zhai)—refers
to the gathering of grassroots antigovernment rebels into for-
tresses located in remote, mountainous areas. The name shan-
zhai in Chinese mobile phones has a double meaning: the first
denotes that illegal phones originated from rebel strongholds,
namely the informal economy; the second implies that rebels
gathered in numbers large enough to challenge the status quo.
bs_bs_banner
Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal
Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 8: 16–36 (2014)
Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com). DOI: 10.1002/sej.1174
Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management Society
champion’ policy that restricted competition in the
mobile phone sector.2In October 2007, after years
of suppression, negotiation, and bargaining, the
Chinese state finally reached a compromise by aban-
doning its license control over mobile phones. This
regulatory change enhanced not only the legitimacy
of shan-zhai economic activities, but also their legal
standing. The phenomenon is striking. The Wall
Street Journal heralded shan-zhai as ‘the sincerest
form of rebellion in China’ (Canaves and Ye, 2009),
one that has spread with such vigor that, in the words
of a New Yorker columnist, ‘all of China is a knock-
off’ (Osnos, 2009). This remarkable evolution
prompted us to consider as our primary research
question how China’s shan-zhai mobile phone sector
developed, grew, and interacted with the state.
To address this question, we draw on the concept
of institutional entrepreneurship (Battilana, Leca,
and Boxenbaum, 2009; Hardy and Maguire, 2008),
which emphasizes the importance of skillful and
effortful agency by institutional entrepreneurs who
leverage resources for achieving institutional change
and innovation. Institutional entrepreneurship’s
account of embedded agency and change process
resonates with the challenges faced by informal
entrepreneurs aspiring to reach beyond their institu-
tional boundaries and act in concert with the formal
institutions of the state. We consider Chinese shan-
zhai entrepreneurs to be institutional entrepreneurs
who proactively sought to enhance their legitimacy
to generate momentum for regulatory change. As
argued by Deephouse and Suchman (2008: 62),
‘legitimacy can appear continuous . . . (and) vary in
its certainty and security’ (emphasis in original). As
informal entrepreneurs become more firmly legiti-
mate and become legitimate to more audiences, a
state can eventually agree to confer legality or ‘regu-
latory legitimacy’ (Deephouse and Suchman, 2008;
Scott, 2001). From this point, the transition from
informal economy to formal economy, although not
yet complete, progresses rapidly enough so as to
seem inevitable.
Our analysis of the Chinese shan-zhai sector
uses qualitative procedures and emphasizes the
strategizing activities of institutional entrepreneur-
ship (Lawrence and Suddaby, 2006; Vaara and
Whittington, 2012). We examine in detail what
nascent Chinese entrepreneurs, manufacturers, and
vendors actually said and did during their interac-
tions with government policy, their mobilization of
collective actions, and their exploitation of outside
resources and technologies. Our examination em-
phasizes three kinds of strategic action—framing,
aggregating, and bridging—and discusses how
Chinese vendors used these strategies to bring about
innovation and institutional change. Each of the
strategies operates on a different logic, yet each
allows institutional entrepreneurs to pursue change
and innovation effectively. Framing offers explana-
tions and justifications that appeal to the public;
aggregating offers collective actions to draw
support; and bridging offers alternative rules and
practices with potentially novel applications.
The article proceeds as follows: first, we discuss
the nature of informal economies and briefly review
the literature on institutional entrepreneurship,
focusing in particular on the range of strategies avail-
able to informal entrepreneurs intent on decriminal-
izing or legalizing their activities. Second, we
explain our methodology and introduce our case.
Third, we outline the strategies of framing, aggregat-
ing, and bridging by which Chinese shan-zhai
mobile phone entrepreneurs managed their transition
to the formal economy. We conclude by discussing
the implications of our study for research on infor-
mal economies and institutional entrepreneurship.
THEORETICAL ORIENTATION
Informal economy
The informal economy refers to ‘the set of illegal yet
legitimate (to some large groups) activities through
which actors recognize and exploit opportunities’
(Webb et al., 2009: 492). Activities are considered
legal if they are defined and governed by formal
institutions, including laws and regulations. Informal
economy activities are illegal because they take
place outside of formal institutions, but they can
be legitimate to the extent that their products,
methods, and practices are accepted by certain social
groups, including, for example, immigrants, low-
income people, ethnic neighborhoods, and religious
2The most important state regulation was the ordinance
‘Certain Opinions Concerning Accelerating the Development
of the Mobile Telecommunication Industry’(also called Docu-
ment No. 5), released by the State Council on January 1, 1999.
This ordinance aimed to ‘put mobile phone production in the
state-guided plan’by controlling the licenses for production, the
import of equipment, components, and parts, and the export of
final products. The key to shan-zhai’s contestation was to
remove this regulation (and its associated policies) and thereby
create a level playing field in the mobile phone sector.
China’s Shan-Zhai Mobile Phones 17
Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J.,8: 16–36 (2014)
DOI: 10.1002/sej

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT