Information Asymmetry about Investment Risk and Financing Choice

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12128
Published date01 September 2015
Date01 September 2015
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 42(7) & (8), 947–964, September/October 2015, 0306-686X
doi: 10.1111/jbfa.12128
Information Asymmetry about Investment
Risk and Financing Choice
MUFADDAL BAXAMUSA,SUNIL MOHANTY AND RAMESH P. RAO
Abstract: Though it is generally accepted that information asymmetry has an impact on
capital structure policy, the nature of the information asymmetry is not well understood. Recent
theoretical work and empirical evidence suggests that financing choice depends upon the
information asymmetry associated with the investment risk of the particular use of proceeds.
Consistent with this view, using the sources and uses of funds framework, we find that equity
is used to fund projects with greater information asymmetry about their risk such as research
and development expenditure, while debt is used to fund investments with lower information
asymmetry about their risk such as liquidity enhancement.
Keywords: firm investment, capital structure, information asymmetry
1. INTRODUCTION
The role of information asymmetry in corporate financing has become one of the
basic tenets of capital structure theory. The most enduring version is the popularly
known pecking order (PO) hypothesis posited by Myers and Majluf (1984). The model
predicts that information asymmetry between managers and investors leads to adverse
selection costs, creating a hierarchy of financing preference based on the information
sensitivity of the security. In this scheme, retained earnings are the least information
sensitive, followed by debt, and then external equity. Thus, firms are inclined to fund
their financing deficit first by retained earnings, then by debt issuance, and only as a
last resort by external equity issuance. The intensity of research in this area is only
matched by the lack of empirical consensus for the PO theory.1For example, the
The first author is at Department of Finance, Opus College of Business, University of Saint Thomas, St
Paul, MN. The second author is at Department of Finance, Brooklyn College, City University of New York,
Brooklyn, NY. The third author is at Department of Finance, Spears School of Business, Oklahoma State
University, Stillwater, OK. We would like to thank Rajesh Aggarwal, Alice Bonaime, Richard S. Warr, Abu
Jalal, Sheridan Titman, Puneet Jaiprakash, Hafez Hussain and Jack Wolf for their comments. Wealso thank
seminar participants at the 2010 Financial Management Association, 2011 Eastern Finance Association, 2012
Financial Management Association-Europe, and 2012 Asian Finance Association meetings for providing
useful comments on earlier drafts. We would like to thank Subbu Iyer for his research assistance. (Paper
received December 2014, revised version accepted July 2015).
Address for correspondence: Ramesh P.Rao, Department of Finance, Oklahoma State University, Stillwater,
OK, USA.
e-mail: ramesh.rao@okstate.edu
1 Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999) find some support for the PO theory while Frank and Goyal (2003),
Fama and French (2002, 2005), Wu and Wang (2005) and Leary and Roberts (2010) find significant
evidence against it.
C
2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 947
948 BAXAMUSA, MOHANTY AND RAO
PO theory cannot explain why young, small and non-dividend paying firms that face
large asymmetric information problems, issue equity securities (e.g., Ambarish et al.,
1987; Fama and French, 2002; and Wu and Wang, 2005). Survey findings of Graham
and Harvey (2001) also suggest that small and non-dividend paying firms’ financing
decisions are not consistent with PO theory.
Though evidence in favor of PO is mixed, Leary and Roberts (2010) suggest
that measures of information asymmetry may be systematically related to financing
behavior, albeit not necessarily in sync with the predictions of the PO model.
Specifically, some of the observed patterns with respect to small firms, age, and asset
tangibility suggest that information asymmetry relating to future investments may play an
important role. Recent theoretical work by Fulghieri and Lukin (2001), Wu and Wang
(2005), Halov et al. (2011) and Halov and Heider (2012) provides support for such
a view. These models predict a preference for equity over debt when there is greater
information asymmetry between the firm and outsiders about future investment risk
(i.e., project risk to which the funds are directed). Wu and Wang (2005) also show that
announcement returns associated with issuance of equity are more likely to be positive
when the asymmetric information about firm value arises mainly from growth (future
investment) rather than assets-in-place.
In this paper, we provide empirical evidence to support the notion that the
information asymmetry of the underlying project risk (e.g., relative success of a new
product such as a new drug or the growth potential from a plant expansion) is
what drives financing choice. For testing purposes, we classify investments into a
hierarchy based on their underlying risk information asymmetry: liquidity investments
(lowest risk), capital expenditures (moderate risk) and R&D investments (highest
risk). We argue that liquidity-enhancing investments (e.g., building up cash or working
capital) are associated with fairly low information asymmetry about their risk while,
at the other extreme, investments in R&D are expected to be associated with the
greatest information asymmetry about their project risk. On the other hand, as capital
expenditures tend to be focused on investments in fixed assets, they are assumed to
hold an intermediate position between liquidity-enhancing investments and intangible
investments (i.e., R&D expenditures). Thus, we expect debt financing to be associated
with subsequent low risk information asymmetry liquidity-enhancing investments while
equity financing should be more closely related with high underlying risk information
asymmetry investments such as R&D.
For our empirical methodology we employ the sources and uses of funds framework
used in several studies (e.g., Gatchev et al., 2010; Chang et al., 2014) based on the
accounting identity that the total funds used by the firm should equal internal cash
flows in addition to debt and equity raised by the firm. The primary uses of funds
we consider are research and development expenditure (R&D), capital expenditure,
working capital changes, changes in cash holdings and cash dividends.2We find that
per dollar of equity issued 22 cents is used for R&D, while only 1 cent per dollar of debt
goes toward R&D financing. With respect to capital expenditures, 11 cents of every
dollar of debt financing is devoted to this expenditure in contrast to only 5 cents in the
case of equity financing. A similar pattern is evident for working capital expenditures
where 9 cents of every dollar of debt financing ends up but only 3 cents in the case of
2 Though our focus is on investment related uses of funds, we include dividends to meet the cash flow
identity requirement.
C
2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT