Information and Assumption Risks

AuthorRobert J. Spjut
Pages81-116
4
Information and Assumption Risks
INFORMATION AND ASSUMPTION HAZARDS
Incorrect Information, Processing, and Assumptions
Decisions about transactions are based on information or assumptions in
lieu of information or a combination of both. Information, here used in
the broadest sense, includes any thought communicated about a matter,
the correctness of which can be verified at contract formation or later.
Collecting and evaluating information about a transaction always
has a cost. In a complex transaction, where a party will never have all
the information that might be compiled about that deal, its diligence
costs must be controlled, especially because the marginal value of the
information collected will decrease. A party must decide when it has
sucient information to make decisions about that deal. It will usually
rely on such information unless the party doubts its reliability.
In the best case,
all information on which a party relies is correct,
it correctly investigates, evaluates, and processes whatever
information is received, and
any assumption on which it relies is correct.
81
In the worst case,
any information on which a party relies is incorrect,
it incorrectly processes some or all of the information, and
any assumption on which it relies is incorrect.
Between these extremes are twenty-five other combinations of these
three hazards. The simplest three are the focus of this chapter.
These three combinations are (1) reliance upon incorrect
information, processed correctly, and not supplemented by assumptions;
(2) reliance upon correct information incorrectly processed; and (3)
little or no information, correct and correctly processed as far as it goes,
but supplemented by an incorrect assumption upon which a party relies.
In all instances, the hazard is the reliance upon such information or
assumption. The causes of (1) are the counterparty or third parties, and
the causes of (2) and (3) will be the party.
Following are cases that illustrate hazards (1), (2), and (3),
respectively:
OnBank & Trust Company v. FDIC
1: A government agency became the
conservator of an insolvent savings and loan association, transferred
the mortgage loans the association had made to its customers into
a trust, oered to sell interests in the trust, and described the loans
in a prospectus that overstated the total principal amount of the
loans by approximately $1,000,000, or two percent. The buyer relied
upon the stated amount when bidding for the portfolio.
Smith v. Zimbalist2: Zimbalist, a prominent violinist and collector
of rare violins, visited Smith, another violin collector, inspected
two of his violins, declared they were made by Stradivarius and
Guarnerius, respectively, asked Smith what price he would accept
for the violins, and agreed to pay $8,000 in installments. The buyer
made and relied entirely upon his own evaluation of the violins.
In fact, the violins were imitations. The information available, the
violins, was incorrectly examined.
Backus v. MacLaury3: A livestock breeder decided to bid at an
auction on a calf he intended to use to breed a herd, though
1 967 F. Supp. 81 (W.D.N.Y. 1997).
2 2 Cal.App.2d 324, 38 P.2d 170 (Cal. App. 1934).
3 278 A.D. 504, 106 NYS 2d 401 (N.Y. App. 1951).
Planning and Documentation Risks
82
the calf was then too young for its fertility to be determined. No
information about the fertility of that specific calf was available.
Each bidder had to make an assumption that the calf was or might
be or was not or might not be fertile. The assumption was knowingly
made. Arational bidder who assumed the calf was fertile, as did
the bidder in the case, would bid an amount higher than one who
assumed otherwise. The latter might not bid at all. The bidder’s
assumption proved incorrect.
Benefit Misconceptions
A benefit is misconceived when its expected value or utility is more or
less than can or will be realized. The misconceiving party may or may
not be the one who will realize the benefit. A hazard occurs when a party
relying upon such misconception expects to receive more value or utility
than can or will be realized. A hazard should not occur because one
party expects the other to receive less than can or will be realized unless
it would have realized extra value had such excess not accrued to the
benefit of the other party or it could also have received more value in
exchange without giving more.
A party misconceives a benefit because (1) the information the
party receives and on which it relies about such benefit is incorrect, (2)
the party incorrectly processes good information and relies upon its
conclusion about such benefit, or (3) the party makes and relies upon an
incorrect assumption about such benefit.
Following are two cases that illustrate reliance upon incorrect
information, a feature of hazard (1):
OnBank & Trust Company v. FDIC, which is previously described.4
The prospectus overstated the total principal amount of the loans
the buyer received.
Conti v. Winters
5: The seller stated the car had not been driven more
than 3,500 miles, and the odometer read between 3,400 and 3,500
miles, when, in fact, the car had been driven more than 15,000
miles before being purchased by the seller.
4 See text accompanying note 1.
5 86 RI 456, 136 A.2d 622 (R.I. 1957).
Information and Assumption Risks 83

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT