Informal Consequences of Budget Institutions in the US Congress

AuthorKenneth S. Lowande,Andrew J. Clarke
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12134
Date01 November 2016
Published date01 November 2016
ANDREW J. CLARKE
KENNETH S. LOWANDE
University of Virginia
Informal Consequences of Budget
Institutions in the US Congress
Though considerable research focuses on formal institutions in Congress,
scholars have long acknowledged that much of what guides legislative behavior is
unwritten. To advance this area, we leverage a tool that allows appropriators to redirect
billions of dollars from mandatory programs to discretionary projects. Changes in
mandatory program spending—known as “CHIMPs”—show that existing institutions
are often maintained by the strategic action of legislators. In the case of CHIMPs, we
find their use is largely a response to formal constraints and that they are preserved
through avoidance of minimum reform coalitions. This highlights that the legislative
process—and budgetary outcomes in particular—cannot be understood without attention
to procedures which remain “off the books.”
“We want to protect the problem.”
—CongressionalAide, July 25, 2013,
Interview withauthors
The study of congressional institutions generally focuses on
formal rules and procedures—how they remain stable despite their
conspicuous endogeneity (Adler 2002), how reform is achieved
(Binder 1997; Bovitz, Carson, and Collens 2012; Rohde 1991;
Stewart 1989), and how they inf‌luence policy outcomes (Brady and
Morgan 1987; Primo 2007). Yet scholars have long acknowledged
that much of what inf‌luences legislative outcomes is unwritten.
More specif‌ically, strategic responses to formal rules—which
Krehbiel, Shepsle, and Weingast (1987) call “ripples” in the wake of
institutional change—are critical for understanding these outcomes.
Unfortunately, studying this behavior is challengi ng because it is often
diff‌icult to observe. As a result, explaining the stability and impact of
these strategic responses remains a largely open, critical task for
Congress scholars (and institutionalists,more broadly).
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, 41, 4, November 2016 965
DOI: 10.1111/lsq.12134
V
C2016 Washington University in St. Louis
To advance this research, we leverage a little-known tool that
allows members of appropriations subcommittees to redirect billions of
dollars from mandatory programs to discretionary projects. Changes in
mandatory program spending (known by legislators and their staff as
“CHIMPs”) provide an opportunity to understand the prominence and
stability of behaviors that emerge in direct response to institutional
change. In brief, we show CHIMPs are a strategic response to tight dis-
cretionary spending caps and the rise of mandatory (or “automatic”)
spending. CHIMPs were created to give appropriators the ability to
extract particularistic benef‌its. They endure because they provide sub-
stantial collective benef‌its to congressional majorities, and appropriators
judiciously select programs to prevent the mobilization of reform
coalitions. In making this argument, we make two distinct contributions.
First, we introduce an overlooked and substantively impactful
behavior to the study of congressional politics. CHIMPs are often
described by those with f‌irst-hand knowledge as an indispensable part of
congressional practice. In the words of one staffer, they “have permeated
the entire [appropriations] process.”
1
In 2015, appropriators increased
nonmilitary discretionary spending by 4% (or $19 billion) through
CHIMPs. Despite their dramatic effect on the funding of discretionary
programs, their use has never been the subject of political science
research.
2
As an outcome of study, they pose research challenges that
render systematic analysis diff‌icult. CHIMPs are not contained in the
public reports of the Congressional Budget Off‌ice (CBO), the Off‌ice of
Management in Budget (OMB), or in summary tables of the legislation
itself. Thus, a key contribution of this article is the construction of a data
set of CHIMPs in USDA programs over an 11-year period (2003–2013).
To complement our statistical analysis, we also conducted a series of
elite interviews.
3
Together, these data provide the basis for our analysis.
Second, we show that, in some cases, formal rules provide insuff‌i-
cient explanations for observed outcomes. CHIMPs provide f‌lexibility
and eff‌iciency gains to congressional majorities and improve the bar-
gaining capacity of appropriators. Mandatory spending growth
constrains future Congresses—crowding out discretionary programs
legislators might prefer. CHIMPs temporarily release these commit-
ments without the transaction cost of repealing these programs
wholesale and recycle unspent funding to guide must-pass legislation
through the legislative process. CHIMPs provide a useful response that
maintains the institutional status quo, even as billions in government
spending are shifted to discretionary projects. Thus, an exclusive focus
on Congress’s codif‌ied rules and procedures is likely to obscure the
meaningful behavior of practitioners.
966 Andrew J. Clarke and Kenneth S. Lowande
Since the details of CHIMPs are nontrivial and often unclear, we
begin by describing their role in budgetary politics. Drawing on the
insights of existing work on congressional institutions, we then outline
expectations about the impact of CHIMPs as well as which programs are
likely to be targeted. Adopting a f‌ixed-effects empirical strategy, we
divide our analysis into two distinct sections that seek to explain varia-
tion between and within programs over time, respectively. We f‌ind that
the magnitude of CHIMPs is largely a function of tightening budgetary
constraints. Additionally, we f‌ind that members of Congress (MCs) tar-
get two types of programs: (1) those with concentrated constituency
benef‌its and (2) those that depart from the formulaic characteristics of
traditional entitlements. These empirical regularities ref‌lect the strategic
avoidance of potential reform coalitions, which would threaten the future
use of CHIMPs. Ultimately, these f‌indings shed light on how “off the
books” practices contribute to the stability of existing institutions and
alter legislative outcomes.
Changes in Mandatory Program Spending (CHIMPs)
First, it is important to distinguish CHIMPs from a textbook under-
standing of the budget process.
4
In scholarship on the US budget, the
following story is commonly told. Mandatory programs are those that
have been created by standing committees and obligate the federal gov-
ernment to spend over multiple f‌iscal years. More generally, passing a
law that authorizes a program is analogous to creating a bucket. Manda-
tory programs are pref‌illed buckets; discretionary programs are buckets
that rely on appropriators to be f‌illed. CHIMPs are retroactively enforced
limitations on the amount of budget authority allocated to mandatory
programs.
5
By writing in CHIMPs, appropriators essentially siphon
from those pref‌illed, mandatory buckets.
6
Appropriations staff use
CHIMPs to meet the yearly demand for discretionary spending without
exceeding their annual allotment of budget authority. This annual cap,
known as a 302(b) allocation, represents the amount an appropriations
subcommittee may spend on discretionary programs within its policy
jurisdiction.
Typically, CHIMPs are attached to appropriations bills at the
subcommittee level by staffers directly responsible to their subcommittee
chair. Subcommittee chairs hold primary responsibility for drafting
appropriations bills within their given jurisdiction. Moreover, these
chairs are provided staff and resources to facilitate the yearly appropria-
tions process. Each year, subcommittee staffers—led by chair-appointed
clerks—work through the details of the year’s appropriation bill.
7
967Informal Consequences of Budget Institutions

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT