Inequality, leverage and crises: Theory and evidence revisited

AuthorYang Zhang,Chun Kwok Lei,Pui Sun Tam,Xinhua Gu
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12806
Date01 August 2019
Published date01 August 2019
2280
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec World Econ. 2019;42:2280–2299.
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Received: 28 October 2018
|
Revised: 20 February 2019
|
Accepted: 10 April 2019
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12806
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Inequality, leverage and crises: Theory and evidence
revisited
XinhuaGu
|
Pui SunTam
|
YangZhang
|
Chun KwokLei
Department of Finance and Business Economics,Faculty of Business Administration,University of Macau, Macau, China
Funding information
Research Committee, University of Macau, Grant/Award Number: MYRG2017‐00215‐FBA and MYRG2018‐00140‐FBA
KEYWORDS
asset bubble, financial crisis, GMM regression, inequality, leverage, theoretical framework
JEL CLASSIFICATION
E20; E25; E51; N1
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The Great Recession has spurred a new wave of research on the causes of financial crises. A central
issue under discussion is whether high inequality can be adduced as a causal factor behind the major
crises starting in 1929 and 2007. Rajan (2010) argues that rising inequality creates political pressure
to maintain living standards of the voting public despite their stagnant incomes. Related policy mea-
sures are not reducing inequality levels but encouraging deficit spending via expanded credit. Rajan's
political‐economy argument is confirmed by other authors' observations (e.g., Tridico, 2012; Wisman,
2013). An inevitable consequence of consumer credit growth under rising inequality is the rapid accu-
mulation of private indebtedness (Iacoviello, 2008; Klein, 2015). When such indebtedness starts to be
perceived as unsustainable, a sudden shock such as asset bubble bursting can become the trigger for a
major crisis (Kumhof & Ranciere, 2010; Kumhof, Ranciere, & Winant, 2015). This line of argument
is referred to as the Rajan hypothesis in the literature.
This hypothesis simply reopens the question of the link between inequality and crises, for
the Rajan hypothesis had existed long before Rajan (2010) (van Treeck, 2014). Previously, many
authors pointed out that rising inequality and growing credit had an intimate bearing on ensuing
disasters (Eccles, 1951; Galbraith, 1954; Pollin, 1988; Palley, 1994; Olney, 1999; Frank, 2007;
Barba & Pivetti, 2009; Stiglitz, 2009; UNCE, 2009). Recently, more studies have emerged in
support of the Rajan hypothesis (Galbraith, 2012; IMF & ILO, 2010; Kumhof, Lebarz, Rancière,
Richter, & Throckmorton, 2012; Lucchino & Morelli, 2012; Palley, 2012; Reich, 2010). While
other analyses of crises point to the roles of financial market deregulation, easy monetary policy
|
2281
GU etal.
and current account imbalances (Keys, Mukherjee, Seru, & Vig, 2010; Obstfeld & Rogoff, 2009;
Taylor, 2009), the latest studies are still in line with the Rajan hypothesis (Gu & Huang, 2014;
Kirschenmann, Malinen, & Nyberg, 2016; Kumhof etal., 2015; Stockhammer, 2015). These stud-
ies assert that credit expansion, albeit able to stimulate aggregate demand under high inequality
for some time, would be ultimately unsustainable since it is only a stopgap policy for the problem
of income distribution.
The Rajan hypothesis, while sparking lively debate about the effect of inequality on crises, has
its critics. Rajan (2010) did not emphasise the explosion of wealth for the very top (5% or 1%) of the
income distribution. Top inequality makes it possible to have privileged access to political decisions
via lobbying activities and campaign donations, and this in turn further heightens distributional and
debt problems (Hacker & Pierson, 2010; Volscho & Kelly, 2012). Moreover, the concomitant rise in
income inequality and financial fragility may be due to coincidence rather than causality (Acemoglu,
2011; Krugman, 2010). Furthermore, it is doubtful whether the Rajan hypothesis, applied mainly
to the 2007 US crisis, can be applicable universally to other countries or other crises. Bordo and
Meissner (2012) question the generality of this hypothesis by estimating a long panel with many
cross‐sections. They conclude that financial crises are preceded by credit booms that, however, are
not closely related to rising inequality. Similarly, Atkinson and Morelli (2010) find that high inequal-
ity may not be a common factor causing systemic crises in different countries other than the United
States.
It is necessary to clarify the above controversy by deepening the related research. The Rajan hy-
pothesis actually rejects conventional consumption theories since they have no link of personal con-
sumption with permanent income inequality and propose no policy action for stimulating demand in
response to high inequality (van Treeck, 2014). There is empirical evidence suggesting that rising
inequality may be due to the permanent rather than transitory components of income (Kopczuk, Saez,
& Song, 2010). The lack of attention to inequality among theorists seems to be related both to low
inequality during the first three post‐war decades and their enthusiasm about increased credit avail-
ability as efficient markets’ response to the higher household demand for insurance against the greater
dispersion of transitory income (Greenspan, 1996; Krueger & Perri, 2003). Using permanent income
inequality and relative income hypothesis, Rajan (2010) calls for a renaissance of consumption theory
because inequality that has risen again since the 1980s can no longer be ignored. This serious macro-
economic risk should be incorporated into theoretical models as in our work by considering the effects
on financial systems of permanent inequality and income classes.
Only a few studies along this line appear in the theoretical literature. Kumhof etal. (2015)
complement the Rajan hypothesis with a DSGE model for the links between inequality, debt and
crises. Although they provide a novel approach to the issue, alternative theories are still needed to
deepen our understanding of the complex impacts of income inequality on financial fragility. While
Kumhof etal. make differences by allowing for heterogeneity across income groups compared with
others (Iacoviello, 2008; Krueger & Perri, 2006), they did not address policy interventions that
cause consumption inequality to deviate from income inequality; the link between both types of in-
equality is an important issue in the recent literature (Attanasio & Pistaferri, 2016). In this paper, we
develop a macroeconomic model for this link based on key stylised facts and take into account the
government's role in affecting the inequality–debt–crisis nexus; this role is empirically confirmed
by other authors (Bartels, 2008; Igan, Mishra, & Tressel, 2011). Our model is made analytically
tractable, with a closed‐form solution derived to yield intuitive comparative static results.
This paper also presents a renewed examination of empirical evidence based on our theoretical predic-
tions. The extant works have examined the potential determinants of financial crises by following tradi-
tional approaches in a large literature on credit cycle (Allen, Babus, & Carletti, 2009; Bordo & Meissner,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT