Industry equilibrium with random exit or default

Published date01 August 2019
Date01 August 2019
AuthorPiin‐Hueih Chiang,Svetlana Boyarchenko
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12381
J Public Econ Theory. 2019;21:650686.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet650
|
© 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 12 November 2018
|
Revised: 10 May 2019
|
Accepted: 11 May 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12381
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Industry equilibrium with random exit
or default
Svetlana Boyarchenko
1
|
PiinHueih Chiang
2
1
Department of Economics,
The University of Texas at
Austin, Austin, Texas
2
Department of Economics, National
Chengchi University, Taipei, Taiwan
Correspondence
Svetlana Boyarchenko, Department of
Economics, The University of Texas at
Austin, 2225 Speedway Stop C3100,
Austin, Texas 78712.
Email: sboyarch@utexas.edu
Abstract
An industry consisting of a large number of small price
taking firms subject to idiosyncratic productivity shocks
is considered. At the moment of entry, a firm takes on
debt. We show that in a competitive equilibrium, some
firms exit and pay out their debt while others choose to
default. The outcome depends on the realization of firm
specific shocks. The paper demonstrates that if the firms
selfselect between exit with debt repayment and
default, then the default region is disconnected from
the exit region. The methodological contribution of the
paper is the analytical characterization of the longrun
equilibrium for two scenarios of the initial distribution
of productivity shocks. We consider two public policy
mechanismscontract enforcement and creditor pro-
tection. Our policy recommendation is that regulators
need to reduce the contract enforcement if they want to
decrease the longrun default rate.
KEYWORDS
endogenous default, endogenous exit, heterogeneous firms, industry
equilibrium
JEL CLASSIFICATION
C61; D81; G31; H32
1
|
INTRODUCTION
1.1
|
Motivation
Small businesses are an important part of the economy of virtually every nation. The importance of
small firmsgrowth for economic development has been recognized in policyoriented literature
(see, e.g., Beck, DemirgucKunt, Laeven, & Levine, 2008). According to the US Small Business
Administration, small firms produce more than half of US nonfarm output, employ 50% of workers,
and pay 45% of total private payroll. Small firms represent 99.7% of all employer firms. Small firms
are an important source of income for the poor in developing countries. Ninety nine percent of the
firms in many poor countries have 10 or fewer workers (see, McKenzie, 2017). Many micro
enterprises in developing countries have high returns to capital, but also face risky revenue streams
(see de Mel, McKenzie, & Woodruff, 2019). In principle, equity offers several advantages over debt
when financing investments of this nature, but the use of equity in practice has been largely limited
to investments in much larger firms. Although there is a lot of optimism about the power of finance
for smallscale business development, a growing literature (see, e.g., de Mel et al., 2019; Inekwe,
2019; McKenzie & Paffhausen, 2018) shows that success cannot be taken for granted and may
critically depend both on the entrepreneurs personal characteristics and on institutions.
The goal of this paper is to understand how small firmsentry and exit decisions are affected
by industrywide and firmspecific exogenous parameters and procedures and to provide policy
recommendations. We leave for the future analysis of the optimal business tax policy as in
Becker and Schneider (2017).
Small firms rely heavily on external finance. Picard and Rusli (2018) emphasize the
importance of private debt financing in reducing government transfers and information costs.
Small firms have historically faced significant difficulties in accessing funding for positive net
present value (NPV) projects due to lack of credible information about them by potential
providers of funds. Maybe due to creditorscautiousness, bankruptcy rate (at least in the United
States) is low: The average annual default rate on small business administration (SBA) loans is
3.5% according to Glennon and Nigro (2005). Hillegeist, Keating, Cram, and Lundstedt (2004)
document that the average annual bankruptcy rate for US firms was 1% from 1980 to 2000.
Mester (1997) estimates the annual default rate for business loans as ranging between 1% and
3%. Herranz, Krasa, and Villamil (2015) use the Survey of Small Business Finances
administered by The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the US Small
Business Administration, data and find a large percentage of entrepreneurs who inject personal
funds to keep their firms alive. This may seem puzzling because incorporated firms are
protected by limited liability in case of bankruptcy. Negative equity and low default rates
indicate that bankruptcy is a strategic decision.
In the United States, businesses can file Chapter 7 or 11 for bankruptcy. Chapter 11 is
designed for large firms, or corporations negotiating debt restructuring while continuing their
operations. Chapter 7 is primarily intended as a bankruptcy procedure for consumers, but it is
also de facto a bankruptcy procedure for small firms. After filing for Chapter 7, an entrepreneur
gets a fresh startin the sense that debts are discharged and all future earnings are exempt
from debt payments.
Death or exit rates of small firms are fairly high. McKenzie and Paffhausen (2018) find that small
firms die at an average rate of 8.2% per year. Due to high exit rates of small firms, creditors face not
only default risk, but also prepayment risk, that is why it is really important to understand why
some small businesses partially financed by debt choose to exit and pay out their debt, while others
file for bankruptcy as well as creditor protection and contract enforcement mechanisms.
1.2
|
Contribution and results
The main contribution of this paper is to derive an equilibrium model for a competitive industry
that, due to technological reasons, is composed of small firms and to demonstrate how small
BOYARCHENKO AND CHIANG
|
651
firms selfselect between default and exit with debt prepayment. Our numerical results produce
the exit rate at least two times higher than the default rate, which agrees with empirical findings
listed above. Our model also shows that when exit and default are strategic decisions, firms are
making negative profits before liquidation. Hence, the entrepreneurs have to inject their own
money to cover business losses. This agrees with empirical findings of Herranz et al. (2015).
We derive analytical expressions for equilibrium output price, debt coupon rate, entry rate of
new firms, and stationary distribution of active firms. We also describe analytically the
following four state space regions.
1. The good luck zone (the upper tail of the initial distribution of shocks): Firms in this zone
are the most productive ones. Eventually, they will exit, but they never default.
2. The exit zone (adjacent to the left boundary of the good luck zone): The entrepreneur finds
out that her own prospects are not too good but the investment project has sufficiently high
scrap value, so that it makes sense to sell the firms assets and pay back the debt.
3. The default zone (the lower tail of the initial distribution of shocks): The entrepreneur
observes that the future is too bleak and defaults immediately.
4. The Buridan zone (an interval that separates the default and exit zones): The entrepreneur
observes that her prospects are not great, but it is optimal to remain active, so she goes on
producing. If eventually the shock enters the default zone first, the firm defaults. If instead
the shock enters the exit zone first, then the firm pays the debt and exits. While the
entrepreneur is indecisive, her behavior resembles the behavior of the famous animal placed
between two piles of hay.
The novelty of prediction of our dynamic model is that the default zone is disconnected from
the exit zone, so that there are relatively unproductive firms that remain active for some time.
The dynamics of the firms inside the Buridan zone suggests that the firms may leave the
industry after a sequence of favorable productivity shocks. The reader must keep in mind that
the initial productivity shock of a firm in the Buridan zone is rather low. Had the entrepreneur
invested only her own assets in the project, she would have sold the firm immediately and
exited the industry. Since the project is partially financed by debt, the entrepreneur cannot sell
the firm immediately, because the value she will recover is insufficient to pay back the debt. At
the same time, the entrepreneur is too good to file for bankruptcy. She can always do this later if
her productivity worsens. So she needs a sequence of successful realizations of revenues to be
able to sell the firm at the scrap value that will at least be high enough to pay back the debt.
Exit from the Buridan zone with debt repayment can be interpreted as an intraindustry
liquidation. Fleming and Moon (1995) find that many liquidating firm assets are sold to firms
operating in the same industry. They describe such voluntary liquidations as an interesting
example of efficient and orderly asset reallocation. Since a voluntary liquidation is conducted at
managements discretion, managers choose to liquidate when financial factors make it value
increasing for the firm. Fleming and Moon (1995) also document that liquidating firms
experience positive abnormal returns in the period preceding liquidation announcement. They
suggest that the market anticipates the firms liquidation and responds to this value enhancing
action.
Being able to characterize equilibrium values analytically is very important, because
comparative statics analysis becomes possible. In particular, we study how equilibrium values
depend on parameters that comprise contract enforcement and creditor protection mechanisms.
The contract enforcement is captured in our model by a penalty for debt prepayment, and
652
|
BOYARCHENKO AND CHIANG

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT