Industrial Policy in the United States: A Neo-Polanyian Interpretation

AuthorJosh Whitford,Andrew Schrank
Published date01 December 2009
Date01 December 2009
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0032329209351926
Subject MatterArticles
Politics & Society
37(4) 521 –553
© 2009 SAGE Publications
Reprints and permission: http://www.
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0032329209351926
http://pas.sagepub.com
Industrial Policy in the United
States: A Neo-Polanyian
Interpretation
Andrew Schrank1 and Josh Whitford2
Abstract
The conventional wisdom holds that U.S. political institutions are inhospitable to
industrial policy. The authors call the conventional wisdom into question by making
four claims: (1) the activities targeted by industrial policy are increasingly governed by
decentralized production networks rather than markets or hierarchies, (2) “network
failures” are therefore no less threatening to industrial dynamism than market or
organizational failures, (3) the spatial and organizational decentralization of production
have simultaneously increased the demand and broadened the support for American
industrial policy, and (4) political decentralization is therefore likely to improve the
functioning of industrial policies designed to combat network failures.
Keywords
industrial policy, networks, federalism, Polanyi, governance
A substantial body of literature addresses the alleged merits and putative preconditions
of industrial policies designed to foster adjustment and economic growth. Industrial
policies that ostensibly combat market failures in centralized polities are purportedly ill
at ease in their decentralized counterparts, and no less “sympathetic” an observer than
sociologist Frank Dobbin therefore finds it hard to believe that an American “industrial
policy would meet with success, as in Japan, rather than with disaster, as in Britain.”1
Nor is Dobbin alone. “Political sociology’s conventional wisdom suggests that Ameri-
can state structure is better suited to inchoate, misguided bailouts characterized by
political graft than to coherent, disinterested, planning on the Japanese model.”2
1University of New Mexico, Albuquerque, NM, USA
2Columbia University, New York, NY, USA
Corresponding Author:
Andrew Schrank, Department of Sociology, University of New Mexico, Albuquerque, NM 87131, USA;
phone: (505) 277-8805
Email: schrank@unm.edu
522 Politics & Society 37(4)
This article calls the conventional wisdom into question, however, by making four
key points about the relationship between economic needs and political possibilities in
the contemporary United States: first, that the activities most likely to be targeted by
industrial policy are increasingly governed by decentralized production networks
rather than competitive markets or vertically integrated corporations; second, that
“network failures” are therefore no less threatening to industrial dynamism than
“market failures” or “organizational failures”; third, that the spatial and organizational
decentralization of production have simultaneously increased the demand and broad-
ened the support for industrial policy in the United States; and fourth, that political
decentralization is likely to improve, rather than inhibit, the functioning of industrial
policies designed to combat network failure in the U.S. context.3 We therefore conclude
that the development of a theory of network failure capable of guiding intervention into
the network economy is an urgent task not only for economic sociology but for pro-
gressive politics as well.
Our argument draws explicitly on a “neo-Polanyian” approach to political econ-
omy in that it simultaneously rejects the idea “that the economy is autonomous and
obeys a single logic” and recognizes the ebb and flow of laissez-faire and social
protection—that is, the pendular swing at the heart of Polanyi’s Great Transformation
as the principal source of dynamism in capitalist society.4 Part I sets the proverbial
stage by placing the neo-Polanyian interpretation against the backdrop of three earlier
approaches to industrial policymaking—orthodox market fundamentalism, liberal
market skepticism, and neo-institutionalism—that gave analytical pride of place to
path dependence and market failure.5 Our goal in so doing is less to fight a three-front
war than to trace the evolution of the “industrial policy debate” over time.6 Part II
portrays contemporary American industrial policies not as path-dependent legacies of
decentralized political institutions but as open-ended responses to the decentralization of
economic activity and in so doing identifies network failures as their unacknowledged—
and heretofore unnamed—targets. Network failures arise where the social and political
requisites of productive decentralization fail to obtain, and actors who would other-
wise reap the rewards of reciprocity are tempted—if not necessarily compelled—to
abandon “network forms of organization” for suboptimal markets or hierarchies.7 Part
III holds that network failures are best addressed not by abandoning network forms of
organization but by pursuing industrial policies that are simultaneously designed to
ensure their success and at home in the U.S. political context. While federalism and
the separation of powers are admittedly incompatible with the development of an
“integrated economic strategy” like the one adopted by postwar Japan, they all but
guarantee experimentation, diversity, and the exploitation of local knowledge and in
so doing allow decentralized production networks to flourish.8 And Part IV concludes
by calling for the development of a theory of network failure designed not only to
advance the intellectual project of the new economic sociology but to contribute to a
progressive policy agenda by facilitating policy responses to the malfunctioning of the
network economy. Existing theories of market and organizational failure dominate the
contemporary policy discussion in part because they serve to diagnose problems and
Schrank and Whitford 523
direct public and private officials toward meaningful solutions. A viable theory of
network failure will have similar practical payoffs and will simultaneously place the
new economic sociology on a sounder theoretical footing.
I. Intellectual Context
Fred Block provides our analytical point of departure by developing a “neo-Polanyian”
perspective on comparative capitalism. Block holds that modern market economies are
not only “embedded in legal, cultural, and political frameworks,” à la Polanyi, but are
simultaneously inoculated against systemic crisis by a variety of buffers and control
mechanisms.9 “A catastrophic failure that spreads from one part of the economy to
others is still possible,” he writes, “but such events are unlikely and unusual. The
more typical pattern is that economic and political actors find ways to keep strains
and difficulties in one part of the economic mechanism from having a dramatic
impact elsewhere.”10
The buffers and control mechanisms in question include taxes, regulations, subsi-
dies, and public (or quasi-public) goods. They are simultaneously sources and symptoms
of the so-called double movement between laissez-faire and social protection described
by Polanyi. And their constant invention and reinvention ensure that market societies
and institutions are not only less homogeneous but less path-dependent than existing
theories allow.11 The neo-Polanyian position can therefore be defined in terms of its
commitment to three broad analytical principles: the “always embedded” nature of
economic activity, the multiplicity of “ways to make a capitalist economy work,” and
the double movement of privatization and protection that brings the system to life.12
The debate over the likelihood and desirability of an American industrial policy
provides a particularly useful test of the neo-Polanyian strategy, for industrial policies
are classic examples of capitalist control mechanisms, and the leading approaches to
their study tend to deviate from at least one of the aforementioned principles.13 In fact,
the best-known argument against industrial policy—and the principal target of Block’s
2008 critique—is a market fundamentalist position that rejects all three neo-Polanyian
commitments.14 Market fundamentalists portray the market as a natural and self-
regulating institution, the competitive process as an unforgiving source of productive
optimization, and the “protective countermovements” anticipated by Polanyi as short-
sighted threats to growth and efficiency.15 While market fundamentalists accept the
reality of market failure and the possibility of corrective action in theory, they hold that
government failure is more common and militates against corrective action in practice.
The market fundamentalist approach to industrial policy is therefore best encapsulated
by Gary Becker’s confident assertion that “the best industrial policy is none at all.”16
The first round of the industrial policy debate pitted market fundamentalists like
Becker against market skeptics like Robert Reich, Barry Bluestone, and Bennett
Harrison more than a quarter of a century ago.17 Market skeptics recognize that “gov-
ernment creates the market,” and thereby embrace the embeddedness assumption, but
simultaneously doubt that “there are multiple strategies for maintaining or improving a

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT