Income Inequality and Ideological Positions in the U.S. Congress

Published date01 September 2021
Date01 September 2021
DOI10.1177/1065912920922318
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/1065912920922318
Political Research Quarterly
2021, Vol. 74(3) 599 –614
© 2020 University of Utah
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/1065912920922318
journals.sagepub.com/home/prq
Article
Two of the most critical, dominant, and studied national
trends in modern American politics are increasing income
inequality (APSA Task Force Report 2004; Atkinson,
Piketty, and Saez 2011; Piketty and Saez 2003) and
increasing ideological and partisan polarization, particu-
larly in the U.S. House of Representatives (Aldrich 1995;
Fiorina 2002; Jones and McDermott 2009; Rohde 1991;
Theriault 2008). As each of these trends has continued to
rise, there is also an emerging literature addressing vari-
ous aspects of these two phenomena. These include the
effects of the rise of partisan class differences (Stonecash
2000); the effects of income inequality on ideological
polarization (IP) in the U.S. Senate (Garand 2010; Hayes
2013) and state legislatures (Chaker 2017); the increasing
influence of district income on the ideological positions
of the members of the U.S. House (McCarty, Poole, and
Rosenthal 2006, 34–44); the effects of income and/or
income inequality on public opinion, citizen partisanship,
and voting (Bartels 2008; Gelman 2008; Gilens 2005;
Kelly and Enns 2010; McCarty, Poole and Rosenthal
2006; Newman and Hayes 2019; Soss and Jacobs 2009);
and the direct national-level relationship between the two
aggregate trends (Duca and Saving 2015; Kwon 2015).
All of these studies, and others, offer important theo-
retical and/or empirical insights. And, many studies—
like the popular impression—often suggest that the
increase in both of these aggregated national-level trends
are causally connected. Yet, no study has directly theo-
rized and tested the individual-level causal relationship
that must underlie these well-known aggregated national-
level trends: specifically, the effect of district-level
income inequality on the ideological positions for indi-
vidual members of the U.S. House of Representatives.
This is especially troubling for at least three main rea-
sons. First, although the aggregated national-level trends
seem graphically convincing, the actual underlying indi-
vidual-level relationships should not be inferred from
them. To infer individual-level behavior from aggregate-
level trends runs the risk of ecological fallacies. Second,
much of the current literature that discusses or analyzes
income inequality often imply, assume, or posit different
economic contexts and different theoretical relationships.
When these are logically compared, they actually lead to
a number of different, but typically unstated and unex-
plored, individual-level political outcomes. Interestingly,
many of these outcomes do not logically suggest an
increase in ideological and partisan polarization of
922318PRQXXX10.1177/1065912920922318Political Research QuarterlyLadewig
research-article2020
1University of Connecticut, Storrs, USA
Corresponding Author:
Jeffrey W. Ladewig, Associate Professor, Department of Political
Science, University of Connecticut, 365 Fairfield Way, U-1024, Storrs,
CT 06269, USA.
Email: jeffrey.ladewig@uconn.edu
Income Inequality and Ideological
Positions in the U.S. Congress
Jeffrey W. Ladewig1
Abstract
Over the past twenty years, there has been much discussion about two of the most important recent trends in
American politics: the increase in income inequality in the United States and the increase in ideological and partisan
polarization, particularly in the U.S. House. These two national-level trends are commonly thought to be positively
related. But, there are few tested theoretical connections between them, and it is potentially problematic to infer
individual-level behavior from these aggregate-level trends. In fact, an examination of the literature reveals, at least,
three different theoretical outcomes for district-level income inequality on voter and congressional ideological
positions. I explore these district-level theoretical and empirical possibilities as well as test them over decades with
three different measures of income inequality. I argue and demonstrate that higher district levels of income inequality
are related to higher levels of ideological liberalism in the U.S. House. This stands in contrast to the national-level
trends, but it tracks closely to traditional understandings of congressional behavior.
Keywords
U.S. Congress, ideology, income inequality
600 Political Research Quarterly 74(3)
members of Congress (MCs). Third, there is often an
incongruent matching of theory and data: income is
sometimes used when an actual measure of income
inequality is posited, national-level data are sometimes
used to describe district-level phenomena, and the theo-
retical discussions rarely differentiate among these.
Given the attested importance of both income inequality
and ideological positioning—much less the combination
of the two—such a mix of inferences, theories, and results
calls for a treatment that tries to bridge the differences in
the current literature as well as theoretically and empiri-
cally examines directly any potential relationship between
district-level income inequality and the ideological posi-
tioning of MCs.
In order to fill these critical gaps between these two
vital issues, this manuscript makes two primary contribu-
tions. First, I argue that the literature on income inequal-
ity and MCs’ ideological responses suggests two critical
questions: How does the national-level income inequality
trend disaggregate to congressional districts? And, in
light of income inequality, do MCs still represent their
constituencies as the traditional congressional literature
would suggest? These questions are foundational to any
study of congressional representation, in general, and of
these two phenomena, in particular. Second, a possible
reason why there has been no studies that directly analyze
district-level income inequality and the ideological posi-
tions of members of the U.S. House is that there is little
consistent district-level data on income inequality over
time. The U.S. Census has now offered a measure of con-
gressional district-level income inequality since 2006.
This is a good start. But, to get a longer time series that
can better capture some of the critical moments in both
time series, I also develop and employ an original data set
that measures income inequality at the district-level from
1993 to 2016.
In sum, I argue and demonstrate that the increasing lev-
els of income inequality at the national level are generally
replicated in most congressional districts, but these dis-
trict-level increases are related to higher levels of ideo-
logical liberalism among all MCs—Democrats and
Republicans alike. As such, despite the popular percep-
tions as well as the graphical appeal of the national-level
trends, income inequality does not seem to be a direct
source of partisan IP. This conclusion, however, does track
closely to the traditional theoretical and empirical under-
standings of congressional and voter behavior. Specifically,
the higher the level of district income inequality, the
median voter is by definition relatively poorer, and thus,
the greater the constituent pressures on the MC for some
form of economic liberalism. In these ways, this study
takes significant steps forward in better understanding
both of these vital phenomena in American politics today.
Theoretical Relationships between
Income Inequality and Ideological
Positions
The topics of income inequality and of congressional
polarization have been prominently intertwined by aca-
demics and journalists. Many of these discussions tap
into, but also deviate from, traditional understandings of
constituent representation and congressional behavior.
The possible connection between income inequality and
congressional polarization is largely inferred from the
two national-level trends being graphically quite similar.
The Gini coefficient (GC) is probably the most recog-
nized measure of income inequality. It typically scores
the income variation among individuals, families, or
households within a given geographic area. The scores
range from zero, which indicates a perfectly equal distri-
bution of income, to one, which indicates that a single
measured unit earns all of the income and the rest of the
units do not earn any income. The annual GC for families
in the United States indicates that the level of income
inequality was at a relatively low level (average GC =
~.36) and often decreasing from the beginning of the
post–World War II era through the mid-1970s. But, in the
mid-1970s, there is an inflection point, and the GC
increases rather steadily since then to a series high (GC =
.452) in 2016 (see Figure 1).
The figure also shows that IP in the U.S. House fol-
lows a very similar pattern (r = .95). The IP measure can
range from zero, which indicates that the two parties have
identical ideological medians, to 2, which indicates that
the median member of one party is perfectly conservative
Figure 1. National income inequality and ideological
polarization: 1947–2017.
Source. The annual Gini data are from the U.S. Census (see https://
www2.census.gov/programs-surveys/cps/tables/time-series/historical-
income-families/f04.xls). The ideological polarization scores for each
Congress are derived from the DW-NOMINATE data (see https://
voteview.com).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT