Incentivizing Regulatory Participation: Effectiveness of a Fundraising Levy
Published date | 01 May 2021 |
Author | Alasdair C. Rutherford,Diarmuid McDonnell,Eddy Hogg |
Date | 01 May 2021 |
DOI | http://doi.org/10.1111/puar.13176 |
Research Article
532 Public Administration Review • May | June 202 1
Abstract: In the absence of a statutory instrument to enforce payment of a regulatory fee, regulators must rely on a
combination of “carrots” and “sticks” to encourage financial contributions by the organizations they oversee. In contrast
to studies of public funding of nonprofits, this article empirically evaluates the effectiveness of a government policy to rely
on nonprofit funding of statutory regulation. The authors exploit a sharp discontinuity in the eligibility threshold for
charities contributing to the new Fundraising Regulator in England and Wales to estimate a causal effect of the levy on
participation. The article shows that the regulator’s threat to “name and shame” was effective at incentivizing regulatory
participation and generating income, but it raises some concerns about the long-term viability of this approach. The
results are significant at a time when many jurisdictions are considering how best to fund the regulation of nonprofits.
Evidence for Practice
• This research examines the effectiveness of a “name-and-shame” strategy pursued by a charity regulator to
encourage organizations to contribute to the cost of their regulation.
• Fundraising charities place high value on their reputations, and the threat of being named and shamed by
the Fundraising Regulator for not paying the fundraising levy was one that charities took seriously.
• The way the Fundraising Regulator implemented the levy—by sending invoices to eligible charities, thereby
playing down the “voluntary” nature of the levy—was necessary to get charities to join. This was especially
the case for medium-sized organizations.
• Cost was not a significant barrier to membership in the Fundraising Regulator for most charities, and so
charities do not seem to be very price sensitive. However, this also means that altering the levy fee bands may
not result in significantly higher or lower numbers of paying organizations.
• The estimated income for the Fundraising Regulator attributable to the name-and-shame approach was
significant (approximately £900,000 per annum), and without this, it is likely that the level of resources available
for fundraising regulation, particular for a new and unproven fundraising regulator, would be significantly lower.
Alasdair C. Rutherford
University of Stirling
Incentivizing Regulatory Participation: Effectiveness of a
Fundraising Levy
An important role for regulators across the
world is to increase the trust of consumers
and/or the public in the sector that is being
regulated (Keating and Thrandardottir 2017). In
many sectors, the violation of regulations by a few
can have a negative externality, affecting trust even in
other organizations that conform with the regulation
(Kilpatrick and Lapsley 1996). But regulators can also
take actions that may undermine broader trust in their
sector, particularly when they highlight bad practice.
This is a tension in accountability: good transparency
can incentivize compliance with regulatory
requirements, but it also risks undermining trust in a
sector if it shows violations to be widespread.
A thorny issue in the establishment of many regulators
is how they are to be funded. Regulators that are
dependent on registration fees from the organizations
they regulate may use a combination of “carrots”
and “sticks” to gain sufficient participation, both to
achieve legitimacy as well as to be financially viable.
The carrots are often fairly clear: a potential gain in
reputation from demonstrating conformity with the
regulatory requirements, perhaps by being listed in
a register with an accompanying mark of approval
(May 2005). In terms of sticks, traditionally regulators
would adopt a “command and control” approach
to compel participation; for example, in the field
of environmental governance, regulators would
command firms to reduce emissions and control how
they did so (e.g., by specifying technologies) (Prakash
and Potoski 2012). In the absence of statutory
powers, regulators often rely on information-based
approaches such as implementing voluntary disclosure
regimes and threatening further statutory regulation
if there is noncompliance (Busuioc and Lodge 2017;
Prakash and Gugerty 2010). Another option is for the
Eddy Hogg is a lecturer in social policy
at the University of Kent. His research looks
at volunteering, charitable giving, and
public attitudes toward the voluntary sector.
Recently, he has worked on volunteering
in public services, youth volunteering,
charitable giving and volunteering in
schools, the value of charity involvement
in supporting young people, fundraising
regulation, and public attitudes toward
charity regulation in England and Wales.
E-mail: e.hogg@kent.ac.uk
Diarmuid McDonnell is a research
fellow in the Third Sector Research Centre,
University of Birmingham. His research
explores the interrelated topics of charity
risk, regulation, and accountability using
linked administrative data derived from
charity regulators internationally. He
has methodological interests in the use
of administrative data for social science
research, data science, and policy evaluation
methods.
E-mail: d.mcdonnell.1@bham.ac.uk
Alasdair Rutherford is professor of
social statistics in the faculty of Social
Sciences at the University of Stirling. His
work uses large administrative data sets
and secondary social survey data to address
research questions pertaining to charity risk,
regulation, and finance in charities across
countries and jurisdictions. An economist by
training, he is also interested in developing
the capacity of both regulators and charities
to make use of the administrative data they
generate.
E-mail: alasdair.rutherford@stir.ac.uk
Public Administration Review,
Vol. 81, Iss. 3, pp. 532–542. © 2020 by
The American Society for Public Administration.
DOI: 10.1111/puar.13176.
Diarmuid McDonnell
Eddy Hogg
University of Birmingham
University of Kent
To continue reading
Request your trial