Importing the Merger Guidelines Market Test in Section 2 Cases: Potential Benefits and Limitations

AuthorDavid G. Mangum,Duncan J. Cameron,Mark A. Glick
Published date01 March 1997
Date01 March 1997
DOI10.1177/0003603X9704200110
Subject MatterDomestic Antitrust
The Antitrust Bulletin/Spring J997
Importing the Merger Guidelines
market
test in section 2cases:
potential benefits and limitations
BY MARK A. GLICK,* DUNCAN J. CAMERON**
and DAVID G. MANGUM***
121
One essential element of any monopolization claim under section
2
of
the Sherman Act is monopoly power in a relevant antitrust
market.I
The
definition
of
the relevant market in Sherman
Act
section 2cases is often
of
signal importance in determining the
outcome
of
the controversy. As in merger cases, the purpose
of
*Professor of Economics, University
of
Utah, Salt Lake City, Utah.
** Vice President, Capital Economics, Los Angeles, California.
*** Chair of Antitrust Practice Group, Parsons Behle &Latimer, Salt
Lake City, Utah.
AUTHORS' NOTE: We wish to thank Rudolph Perit;
and
John Flynn
for
their comments on earlier drafts.
See United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71 (1960)
("The offense of monopoly under §2 of the Sherman Act has two ele-
ments: (1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and
(2) the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished
from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product,
business acumen, or historic accident").
©1997 by Federal Legal PUblications. Inc.
122
The antitrust bulletin
the market definition exercise in a section 2 case is to identify all
of
the important restraints on the ability of the defendant to exer-
cise market power. A definition of the market that is too broad
will lead to an underestimation of the size and power of the defen-
dant. Amarket defined too narrowly will usually have the oppo-
site effect.
For more than half a century, the Supreme Court has grappled
with relevant market issues, producing asomewhat disjointed and
often confusing body of case law attempting to define useful eco-
nomic criteria. Faced with similar problems, in 1982, the Depart-
ment
of
Justice, Antitrust Division, issued significantly revised
Merger
Guidelines
"describing
the
analytical
foundations
of
merger enforcement and providing guidance enabling the business
community to avoid antitrust problems when planning mergers."
Among other innovations, the 1982 Merger Guidelines introduced
asystematic method for defining economically relevant markets,
i.e., markets that
could
be
subject
to a meaningful exercise
of
market
power.
The
Merger
Guidelines
were further revised in
1984 and 1992,
and
the
1992
Merger
Guidelines
were
jointly
issued with the Federal Trade Commission.>
Since its creation, the Guidelines' market definition test has
been utilized by several courts in merger cases.' A LEXIS search
of all federal cases, however, reveals no cases in which the market
test in the Guidelines was applied in a monopolization setting.
This apparent reluctance is somewhat surprising given the courts'
difficulty
developing
apractical market definition test
of
their
own, and the
comparative
rigor of the
Guidelines'
method. No
doctrinal justification supports the courts' reluctance. As early as
1966, the
Supreme
Court
observed
that
there is
"no
reason to
See U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission,
1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 57 Fed. Reg. 41522-01 [hereinafter
Guidelines].
See, e.g., Consolidated Gold Fields, PLC v. Anglo Am. Corp., 698
F. Supp. 467, 501 (S.D.N.Y. 1988); United States v. Rice Growers Ass'n,
1986-2 Trade Cas. (CCH)
11
67,288 (E.D. Cal. 1986); Bon-Ton Stores,
Inc. v. May Department Stores Co., 1994-2 Trade Cas. (CCH)
11
70,800
(W.D.N.Y. Nov. 30, 1994).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT