Humor and Persuasion: The Effects of Laughter during US Supreme Court's Oral Arguments

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lapo.12145
Published date01 April 2020
AuthorTom Pryor,Siyu Li
Date01 April 2020
Humor and Persuasion: The Effects of Laughter
during US Supreme Court Oral Arguments
SIYU LI and TOM PRYOR
Is the decision-making of Supreme Court jus tices influenced by extraneous factors beyond law
and policy? We explore this question by examini ng attorney-induced laughter during ora l
arguments in cases heard by the Court . Drawing on theories of political psychology and social
cognition, we posit that laughter serves as a positive affectivecue that might favorably dispose
justices (albeit subconsciously) to the si de causing the laughter. Analyzing oral argume nt
transcripts during the 1986–93 terms, we find that t he side causing more instances of laughter
is more likely to win the votes of individ ual justices, even while controlling f or other legally
and politically relevant factors. We further find that the effect of laughter is conditional—it
exerts a heightened persuasive po wer on ideologically congruent justices, in noncomplex case s,
and when the legal argumentation is of hi gher quality. Our research thus cont ributes to the
growing literature on personal an d emotional aspects of judicial de cision-making and, specifi-
cally, the emerging scholarly int erest in the role of humor during Supreme Co urt oral
arguments.
The Supreme Court granted certiorari in Rousey v. Jacoway (2005) to tackle the rela-
tively mundane question of whether individual retirement acc ounts were exempt from
bankruptcy under federal law. When the advocate for petitioners, Pamela S. Karlan,
stood up to deliver her final rebuttal, Justice Stevens inform ed her that she had “about
seven minutes. You’re not required to use it all .” Karlan responded, “I’m going to retire
early,” which elicited several appreciative chuckles in the courtroom. In total, four out-
breaks of laughter in the courtroom were cre dited to Karlan while her opponent, Colli
C. McKiever, did not produce any laughter. The petitioner we nt on to win the case in a
9–0 decision.
The petitioners did not win solely because Karlan made the courtroom laugh. Indeed,
the policy stakes in Rousey were high, and justices are professionals. More generally,
much of what we know about the Court suggests that justices vote in a way that maxi-
mizes their policy preferences (Segal and Spaeth 2002) while operating within certain
institutional and collegial constraints (Epstein and Knight 1998; Maltzman, Spriggs, and
Wahlbeck 2000) and within the broad confines of the law (Richards and Kritzer 2002).
The justices might enjoy a good joke as much as anyone else, but the bulk of research
We would like to thank Tim Johnson, Chris Federico, Logan Stundal, Matt Eichinger, the anomymous
reviewers, and the editor of Law & Policy for helpful comments and suggestions. A draft of the article was pres-
ented at the 2019 annual meeting of the American Political Science Association in Washington, DC.
Address correspondence to: Siyu Li, Department of Political Science, 1414 Social Sciences Building,
267 19th Ave. S., Minneapolis, MN, 55455. Telephone: 651-442-9565; Email: lixx5010@umn.edu.
LAW & POLICY, Vol. 42, No. 2, April 2020
©2020 The Authors.
Law & Policy ©2020 University of Denver and Wiley Periodicals LLC.
doi: 10.1111/lapo.12145
ISSN 0265-8240
into judicial decision-making suggests a fleeting moment of levity is a drop in the bucket
compared to the weighty concerns that drive their decisions. More specifically, the pre-
dominant approaches to researching judicial decisions tend to treat judges as hyper-
rational, utility-maximizing automatons.
In contrast, a growing body of research treats Supreme Court justices, perhaps appro-
priately, as human beings and, as such, allows for the possibility that emotions may fac-
tor into their decisions (Black et al. 2011). That is, their personal backgrounds may
influence votes (Wedeking 2012; Glynn and Sen 2015), they may make mistakes
(Guthrie, Rachlinski, and Wistrich 2007), and they might engage in motivated reasoning
(Braman 2006; Braman and Nelson 2007). The point of these analyses is that although
Supreme Court justices are some of the smartest people on the planet, they are still sub-
ject to the same psychological forces that drive the behavior of the mass public.
Humor is certainly no t relevant to the legal mer its of an argument, and a g ood
joke does not change the policy implications of a case. Indeed, if justices are con-
strained by the law and by institutional for ces, or if they are hyper rational policy
maximizers, humor s hould not influence thei r votes on any level. Ho wever, if laugh-
ter during oral argument affects the justices’ votes, even marginally, it would be pow-
erful evidence to support the argument that justices are affected to some degree by
automatic, subcons cious thought proces ses and are influenced b y incidental stimuli.
For our purposes, this means that, while telling a good joke during an oral argument
may be a drop in the bucket compared to every other factor that influences justices’
decisions, there is no telling which drop will cause the bucket to overflow. Literature
on social cognition and political psycho logy has establishe d that much of human rea-
soning occurs throug h largely automatic su bconscious process es (Bargh and Char-
trand 1999) and that inci dental and irreleva nt stimuli can influence our decision s
(Lodge and Taber 2013) . By combining the jud icial decision-maki ng literature with
theories derived from so cial psychology and cogni tion, we explore whether co gnitive
processes common amon g the mass public can exp lain features of elite de cision-
making as well.
Using voice-identified data on the instances of laughter produced by attorneys’
remarks during oral arguments, we find that individual justices are significantly more
likely to vote for the party whose attorney(s) induce more laughter in the courtroom.
This finding constitutes a modest yet important step toward better scholarly understand-
ing of the subconscious aspect of judicial decision-making. Hence, our research comple-
ments Jacobi and Sag’s (2019) argument that centers around how justices purposefully
use humor as a method of advocacy.
Critically, we find the effect of laughter to be intimately conditional on some key
conventional facto rs affecting justices ’ votes: justices’ id eological preferenc es, the legal
complexity of a case, and t he quality of an attorne y’s legal argumentatio n. Specifically,
attorney-induced lau ghter exerts a stronger pers uasive power on ideologic ally compati-
ble justices, in nonco mplex cases, and when t he attorney’s overal l legal argumentation
is better.
The article proceeds as follows. First, it explicates the theoretical background for
why laughter might influence Supreme Court justices during an important stage of their
decision-making process —oral arguments—and then offers several hypotheses about
this phenomenon. From there, it describes the data used to test our hypotheses.
Finally, it present s the results of the stat istical analyses and t hen situates the resu lts
within the literature on judicial politics and the psychology of elite decision-making
more broadly.
©2020 The Authors.
Law & Policy ©2020 University of Denver and Wiley Periodicals LLC.
Li and Pryor LAUGHTER AT THE U.S. SUPREME COURT 163

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT