Humane Capital: A Reexamination of Catholic Social Teachings in Light of the Shift to Human Capital

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12354
Date01 September 2020
Published date01 September 2020
AuthorAndrew Beauchamp
Humane Capital: A Reexamination of
Catholic Social Teachings in Light of the
Shift to Human Capital
By Andrew BeAuchAmp*
ABstrAct. Human capital is the set of productive knowledge, skills, and
traits that individuals possess. Productive knowledge and skills are
typically learned through education and work experience. Character
traits matter both for the application of knowledge and skills and
for their acquisition in the first place. In the past 100 years—and
with enormous social consequences—the economy has transitioned
to human capital being the most important resource for individual
and social outcomes. Societies responded by emphasizing schooling
as the means to develop this resource. In recent decades, however,
researchers have discovered that human capital acquisition depends
on certain character skills best developed early in life before
schooling starts, typically within families. Current research and policy
are investigating which combination of early life schooling and
improvement in family circumstances can best help people acquire
the character skills, and then human capital, needed to flourish. These
changes have important implications for the social teachings of the
Catholic Church, including moral insights into the distribution of
resources, emphasis on the active subject in human work, and the
role of civil society in promoting ideas and institutions conducive to
an ideal human ecology.
Introduction
For much of human history, labor was relatively homogenous. Land
and natural resources, followed later by physical and financial capital,
were the dominant means of production. Their level and distribu-
tion determined the level and distribution of income. The owners of
land and capital were able to dominate agrarian and early industrial
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 79, No. 4 (September, 2020).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12354
© 2020 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc
*Department of Economics, Wright State University. Email: andrew.beauchamp@wright.edu
1210 The American Journal of Economics and Sociology
economies. When ownership of physical capital and land were con-
centrated, inequality was enormous. This was especially significant
in the late 18th and 19th centuries, when the development of large-
scale industrial enterprises devalued the productive capital of skilled
craftsmen and initiated the rise of a substantial working class without
ownership of any significant means of production. Inequalities in the
distribution of productive capital, income, and power arose. Owners
of capital collided with largely unpropertied masses of workers and
triggered intellectual and physical conflict. Social policy in capitalist
countries developed in response to the fear that capitalism would
either create a permanent oligarchy or lead to a socialist revolution
and state ownership of the means of production.
Prior to the 20th century, labor was often equated with manual
labor, without substantial differences in knowledge or development
across people. Even economists downplayed or ignored productive
capacity embodied in people. As Gary Becker (1993: 392) wrote in his
Nobel acceptance speech:
Until the 1950s, economists generally assumed labor power was given and
not augmentable. The sophisticated analyses of investments in education
and other training by Adam Smith, Alfred Marshall and Milton Friedman
were not integrated into discussions of productivity.
At the high point of these debates, the social teachings of the Catholic
Church were launched with Pope Leo XIII’s (1891) Rerum Novarum.
This papal encyclical shared the perspective of the time. It empha-
sized social and economic justice as a moral counterweight to eco-
nomic disparities in productive capacities. In that way, the Church
attempted to moderate the conflict between labor and capital.
By the latter half of the 20th century, however, circumstances in
industrialized countries had reversed. In fact, most of the means
of production were now in workers’ hands, and especially in their
heads and hearts. Today, “human capital,” as economists refer to
these capabilities, is the central determinant of individual well-being
and the wealth of nations. Hamilton et al. (2005) estimate that 80
percent of all wealth in OECD countries arises from some variation
of human capital. To get at this abstract sense of knowledge, skills,
1211Humane Capital
character traits, and institutional arrangements, the World Bank uses
the term “intangible capital.” Many aspects about people and social
relationships factor into human-based productive capacity: knowl-
edge, skills, capacity to work with others, and institutions such as
the rule of law and representative governance. By far the most sa-
lient dimension of human capital for social and economic policy has
been knowledge obtained through education. Thus, in an effort to
increase both individual and social wealth, nations around the world
have provided increasing levels of education for more and more of
their citizens.1
But knowledge cannot be mass produced and spewed out of a
factory. Knowledge is socially embedded. Human capital consists of
more than knowledge. It also includes the willingness, ability, and
motivation to learn, apply, and maintain knowledge in the first place.
The emphasis in recent economic research has shifted to the influ-
ence of character on the capacity of children to build human capital
through their formal education. Character is deeply shaped by local
communities and especially by families. These institutions and social
connections are relevant for children long before they attend formal
schooling. In large measure, character development determines a
person’s trajectory through life.
If human capital has become the dominant means of production,
then knowledge matters. But, as the Nobel Laureate economist James
Heckman has demonstrated, knowledge is a multidimensional object
that takes character as a prerequisite, and character itself has a de-
velopment process of its own. If we want people to have increased
productive knowledge, we need to understand those underlying pro-
cesses. The current emphasis on human capital is a vast change from
an earlier era when the material factors of land and physical capital
dominated. Policies and moral reflection will need to adjust to this
newer reality.
Some of this transition is incorporated in the Church’s social com-
mentary. Catholic social teachings (CST) initially focused, in 1891, on
the distribution of material and productive resources when addressing
poverty, wages, income inequality, unionization, and other aspects
of economic arrangements. By the end of the 20th century, however,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT