How much do online consumers really value free product returns? Evidence from eBay

Published date01 November 2017
AuthorMichael Galbreth,Guangzhi Shang,Mark Ferguson,Pelin Pekgün
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1016/j.jom.2017.07.001
Date01 November 2017
How much do online consumers really value free product returns?
Evidence from eBay
Guangzhi Shang
a
,
*
, Pelin Pekgün
b
, Mark Ferguson
b
, Michael Galbreth
b
a
Florida State University, United States
b
University of South Carolina, United States
article info
Article history:
Received 11June 2016
Received in revised form
30 June 2017
Accepted 7 July 2017
Available online 2 August 2017
Accepted by Dr. Daniel R Guide.
Keywords:
Consumer returns
Online retailing
Marketing-operations interface
eBay
abstract
Consumer return rates have been steadily rising in recent years, resulting in growing costs for retailers
who must manage the returns process and the disposition of returned products. This cost pressure is
driven in part by extremelygenerous return policies, such as giving consumers a full refund upon return.
Interestingly, this common retail practice of full refunds is inconsistent with the recommendations of
many analytical models of returns, which nearly always show that a partial refund is optimal. Such in-
consistencies between theory and practice might arise when the decision drivers include d in the
analytical models do not match the decision drivers in practice. It might also be the case that retailers are
overly optimistic about the value that consumers assign to a full refund, and thus assume that the value
of such a policy outweighs its costs. In this paper, we use data collected from eBay, where identical
products are sold with different return policies, to investigate these open questions in the literature. We
analyze both the return policy drivers from the retailer's perspectiveand the return policy valuefrom the
consumer's perspective. Our results suggest that the value of a full refund policy to consumers may not
be as large as one might expect, and it also exhibits a large heterogeneity across buyers with different
levels of online purchase experience. In addition, we provide empirical evidence for what has long been
suspected by online retailers ethat a non-refundable forwardshippin g charge quickly erodes any value
that consumers assign to return policies. The generality of our results is limited by the fact that eBay
differs from traditional retail contexts in many respects, including the fact that eBay buyers may not be
representative of the general buyer population. However, our study of how eBay consumers value free
returns provides new insights into an understudied area, and it can serve as a starting point for future
studies of the value of return policies in other retail contexts.
©2017 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
An important business challenge for many retailers is the pro-
cessing of consumer returns, i.e. products that consumers return
within the retailer's pre-specied, and often no-questions-asked,
return window. Consumer returns are different than retailer over-
stock returns (to the manufacturer) and end-of-use returns by
consumers (typically occurring after many months or years of use).
The cost of consumer returns is signicant. In 2015, the value of all
consumer returns received byU.S. retailers was estimated at $260.5
billion, an increase of approximately 50% from 2007 (National
Retail Federation, 2008; Ng and Stevens, 2015). A comparable
magnitude of increase has also been observed for return rates in the
past decade (National Retail Federation, 2008, 2016), from below
10% to around 14%. After returns are accepted by retailers, addi-
tional costs such as inspection, return logistics, and refurbishment
or disposal will incur at various steps along the reverse supply
chain,accounting for 5e6% of a typical OEM's revenue and 4% of a
typical retailer's sales (Douthit et al., 2011). It is reported that the
returns-associated reverse logistics costs alone are $40 billion for
the retail sector (Enright, 2003). Moreover, if returnedproducts are
sold to external liquidators and outlet stores, their salvage value is
often only 10%e20% of the original retail price (Stock et al., 2006).
As a result, the management of consumer returns has become one
*Corresponding author.
E-mail address: gshang@business.fsu.edu (G. Shang).
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Journal of Operations Management
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jom
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jom.2017.07.001
0272-6963/©2017Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Journal of Operations Management 53-56 (2017) 45e62
of the top managerial challenges faced by U.S. retailers according to
an industry study by UPS (Brill, 2015).
A signicant contributor to the increasing volume (and cost) of
consumer returns is the popular trend of adopting lenient return
policies. In the past, restocking fees were common among con-
sumer electronic retailers such as mail-order computer dealers
(Chu et al., 1998). Today, however, almost all major retailers offer a
full refund. For example, Best Buy lifted their 15% restocking fee on
consumer electronics in 2010(Reisinger, 2010), while Wal-Marthas
long been offering a 90-day full refund policy. Clearly, retailers
generally believe that a full refund is the best return policy despite
the signicant costs that offering such a policy entails. Given their
unwillingness to reduce the refund amount, most retailers simply
focus on preventing and managing returns through efforts such as
(1) reducing consumer product uncertainty before purchase, e.g.
through buyer assistance programs and virtual tting technology,
and (2) streamlining the operations of the reverse supply chain
after the return (see Pinçe et al. (2016) for a recent example).
Spurred by the magnitude of the costs involved in managing
returns, academic researchers have produced a number of papers
on the topic. The vast majority of this work has been analytical,
with several models investigating the optimal returnpolicies under
various product, market, and consumer characteristics. For
example, Shulman et al. (2009) study a monopoly retailer selling
multiple products, while Hsiao and Chen (2012) consider a broad
notion of quality risk, which encompasses product uncertainty ea
common reason for returns eas a component. In sharp contrast to
practice, these theoretical results almost always recommend a
partial refund, that is, a refund of only a fraction of the original
price.
1
This is also true in studies that examine the effect on a re-
tailer's return policy decision from competition (Shulman et al.,
2011), manufacturer-retailer coordination (Su, 2009), the joint de-
cisions of return policy and inventory (Ketzenberg and Zuidwijk,
2009), open-box sales (Akçay et al., 2013), and end-of-season
markdown pricing (Altug and Aydinliyim, 2016).
At a high level, there are two possible explanations for the
discrepancy between the recommendations from the theoretical
literature (which advises offering partial refunds) and actual retail
practice (offering full refunds). First, it might be that the decision
drivers included in the analytical models, whose goal is to provide
high-level insights, do not closely match the decision drivers used
in practice. That is, the stylized representations of reality in these
models might be inconsistent with how retail managers actually
make decisions regarding return policies. Indeed, although
analytical models of the decision can be quite complex, anecdotal
evidence from industry surveys and news articles suggests that the
reason for choosing full over partial refund in practice can be quite
simple. For example, a majority of consumers review return policies
before purchase (Hsiao and Chen, 2012) and dislike any return-
related fees (O'Neill and Chu, 2003), inuencing retailers to claim
that offering a lenient return policy is simply necessary to keep
them competitive (Chao, 2015). A second possible explanation is
that retailers may be overly optimistic about the value that con-
sumers assign to a full refund, and thus assume (perhaps incor-
rectly) that the value of such a policy outweighs its costs. While the
specic return-related costs (e.g. reverse logistics costs) are rela-
tively easy to quantify for a retailer, the value that consumers
attribute to a return policy is more difcult to measure. Given the
limited empirical evidence on the return policy value, it is difcult
for retailers to make informed decisions regarding the relative costs
and benets of offering full refunds.
This study contributes to the consumer returns literature by
offering empirical insights on both the benets from offering a full
refund and the possible drivers behind this important decision for
the retailer in the eBay context.First, using eBay auction data where
multiple retailers sell the same products through the same channel
but with different return policies, we present an assessment of
whether the three return policy drivers assumed in the analytical
literature (specically: competitive environment, product salvage
value, and retailer reputation) inuence an eBay retailer's return
policy choices. Secondly, we leverage the eBay auction data to es-
timate the value of a full refund policy to consumers using its
impact on the nal auction prices. In the extant literature, Anderson
et al. (2009) was the rst to attempt to empirically quantify the
value of a return policy in the context of a mail-order apparel
retailer, which only offers a full refund for all of the products sold.
The approach used in their paper is to t a structural choice model
to catalog apparel sales (revealed preference data) and approxi-
mate the decrease in the consumer's utility when no refund was
offered by using counterfactual analysis. Because their data is only
from a single retailer that does not change its return policy during
the time of the study, a counterfactual analysis is the only option
available for their study. Heiman et al. (2015) provide another es-
timate for apparel products through a survey (stated-preference
data) where consumers are asked about the discount they are
willing to accept if the return policy is hypothetically removed. As
described in detail below, both our data and our empirical approach
are signicantly different from these previous studies since we
study revealed-preference data in a setting where different re-
tailers sell the exact same products, but some offer full refunds
while others offer no refund. The presence of different retailers
offering different return policies allows us to provide a more direct
comparison. Moreover, our focus on the eBay context enables us to
examine the extent to which the non-refundable shipping charge
might be perceived as a latent restocking feeby consumers. In
addition, we examine how more experienced eBay shoppers might
better estimate their cost of product uncertainty and hence assign a
larger value to a full refund policy. This consumer heterogeneity
aspect adds an important nuance to our ndings that has not been
previously explored.
We provide a brief overview of our research goals and approach
here. Our focus is on small to medium size online retailers (SMEs),
as represented by our dataset of eBay sellers. For SMEs that face the
decision of what type of return policy to offer, we provide an es-
timate of the additional dollar value that consumers place on a
product sold with versus without a full refund policy. Since the
retailers should be able to more easily estimate their internal costs
of offering full refunds, our estimate of the benet side of the
equation should enable them to make more informed decisions. For
retailers who have already made the decision to offer free returns,
we provide an estimate of the premium they can charge for their
products when competing against similar retailers that do notoffer
free returns.
To help answer our research questions, we collected data on
consumer electronics products sold through eBay auctions. We
chose eBay as our data source due to the fact that it includes
identical products sold with different return policies (i.e. full refund
vs. no refund) through different sellers which are mostly small to
medium in size. The reason for our focus on consumer electronics is
two-fold. First, the National Retail Federation (2016)estimates that
return rates for hard goods,including consumer electronics, are
50% more than the grand average across product categories, while
return rates from online sales are twice as large as in brick-and-
mortar stores (Ng and Stevens, 2015). Second, an examination of
the return policies of major online electronics retailers and
1
Full refund does appear as an optimal solution under certain conditions, such as
when product cost and salvage value are both zero, and degree of productdiffer-
entiation are medium in Shulman et al. (2009, see Case 2 in Table 4).
G. Shang et al. / Journal of Operations Management 53-56 (2017) 45e6246

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT