How Labor Market Institutions Matter for Worker Compensation

DOI10.1177/00027162211035965
Date01 May 2021
Published date01 May 2021
Subject MatterInstitutional Outcomes
ANNALS, AAPSS, 695, May 2021 225
DOI: 10.1177/00027162211035965
How Labor
Market
Institutions
Matter for
Worker
Compensation
By
RYAN NUNN
and
JENNIFER HUNT
1035965ANN The Annals Of The American AcademyLabor Market Institutions And Worker Compensation
research-article2021
Labor markets deviate substantially from the competi-
tive ideal, and policies and institutions affect workers’
outcomes. Over the last 45 years, the dramatic increase
in compensation of high earners and weak or stagnant
growth for low and middle earners have shone a spot-
light on the ways in which labor market institutions
sometimes work to the detriment of lower-paid work-
ers. In this article, we survey several institutions—
minimum wages, private sector unions, noncompete
agreements, and occupational licensing—considering
how they have evolved in ways that affect workers’ out-
comes, given that the labor market is characterized by
uneven distribution of market gains. We describe the
modern labor market as one that substantially features
alternative work arrangements and labor market con-
centration, and we consider the implications of this for
public policy. Those policies, along with the surveyed
institutions, are the focus of our final section that dis-
cusses key options for improving worker outcomes.
Keywords: labor market institutions; wages; labor
market policies
The labor market is the primary or only sub-
stantial source of income for most
Americans, and for working-age Americans it is
the primary source of health insurance.
Understanding the determinants of worker
compensation is therefore crucial for improving
Ryan Nunn is the assistant vice president for applied
research in community development and engagement at
the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Previously,
he was a fellow in economic studies at the Brookings
Institution and policy director for the Hamilton Project.
His work has focused on labor market institutions and
outcomes for low- and moderate-income workers.
Jennifer Hunt is a professor of economics at Rutgers
University. She has served as chief economist of the
U.S. Department of Labor and as deputy assistant sec-
retary for microeconomic analysis at the U.S.
Department of the Treasury. Previously, she held posi-
tions at McGill University, the University of Montreal,
and Yale University. Recent research topics include
immigration and wage inequality.
Correspondence: ryan.nunn@gmail.com
226 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
the well-being of Americans. Even as labor economists’ understanding of the
labor market has grown with time, the labor market itself has changed. Core
labor market institutions have changed radically and in ways that correlate with
significant changes in workers’ outcomes, especially increased wage inequality,
and with changes in employer practices.1
In this article, we present basic facts about wage and nonwage compensation,
describe important labor market contexts like alternative work arrangements
and limited labor market competition, and briefly discuss wage setting. We then
discuss key modern labor market institutions that might reflect or contribute to
lower worker bargaining power: the declining federal real minimum wage, the
historically low rate of private sector union membership, noncompete agree-
ments (NCAs), and the rise in occupational licensing. We conclude with a dis-
cussion of ways in which public policies could be changed to improve workers’
outcomes.
The Distribution of Wages and Nonwage Benefits
For families in the lowest, second, and third quartiles of income (i.e., the bottom
75 percent of all families), on average, between 70.2 and 79.4 percent of total
income was from wages in 2016 (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System 2017). The poorest families receive means-tested government transfers
from programs like the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (formerly
the Food Stamp program), and the wealthiest families receive considerable
income from capital investments. But for everyone else, wages and nonwage
benefits constitute all or nearly all of total income.
Figure 1 makes clear that workers have very different experiences. At the bot-
tom (10th percentile) of the distribution, workers earned only $10.32 per hour in
the first quarter of 2020. At the top (90th percentile), workers earned $47.29 per
hour—up from an inflation-adjusted $43.41 in 2009. Inequality in hourly wages
has been rising for decades, an evolution studied in depth elsewhere in the
volume.
Total labor compensation, including nonwage benefits, tends to receive less
attention than wages despite its importance for understanding worker welfare.
Figure 1 also shows percentiles of these nonwage benefits, expressed in terms of
employers’ cost of provision, for the first quarters of 2009 (nested bar in Figure 1)
and 2020.2 These include health insurance, life insurance, retirement savings con-
tributions, and other components of compensation for which employers incur
explicit monetary costs.
NOTE: The views expressed in this document are the authors’ alone and do not necessarily
reflect those of the Federal Open Market Committee or anyone else in the Federal Reserve
System. The authors are grateful to Chris Riddell, Craig Riddell, and The ANNALS editors and
conference participants for insightful suggestions.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT