How Governments Promote Monopolies: Public Procurement in India

Date01 November 2019
Published date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12300
AuthorYugank Goyal
How Governments Promote Monopolies:
Public Procurement in India
By Yugank goYal*
abstract. Government officials exert tremendous power when they
buy goods and services from private companies. By setting the terms
and conditions under which public procurement takes place, public
officials help determine which companies will thrive and which ones
will fail. This is one of the important ways governments help create
and sustain monopolies in the private sector. But since the bidding
process to sell products or services to the government is supposed to
be an open and fair competition, how does it become skewed toward
businesses that already dominate markets? We examine a particular
source of bias: the eligibility criteria for bidding in public procurement
tenders. These criteria often allow a few large, private companies to
bid on government contracts, but they exclude a large number of
small and medium-sized enterprises. We study the terms by which
offers are solicited in India through tenders floated for transportation
projects: roads, highways, bridges, and civil construction. We find that
the eligibility criteria impose an unnecessarily heavy burden on small
firms, potentially knocking them out of the competition and
discouraging them from participating in other procurement processes.
In this way, the process reinforces monopolies instead of breaking
them up. While this study focuses on India, the results also apply to
similar economies.
1. Introduction
As powerful economic subsystems, monopolies influence every aspect
of society.1
In any society where economic power is concentrated
in the hands of a small number of business owners, the aspirations
of a majority of people will be frustrated. If most capital flows into
a few large businesses, fewer people can start their own successful
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 78, No. 5 (November, 2019).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12300
© 2019 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
*Associate professor of economics, O.P. Jindal Global University. Email: ygoyal@jgu.
edu.in
1136 The American Journal of Economics and Sociology
businesses. Society wastes entrepreneurial skills by forcing millions of
people to work for wages instead of applying their own capacity for
innovation and management. Consumers lose because the range and
quality of items for sale is restricted, and prices are likely to be higher
for the goods and services that are produced. The base of democracy
is undermined as the wealth gap enables elites to dominate politics.
Large, monopolistic companies directly influence politics. In some
cases, governments have been elected or defeated according to how
much sympathy they are perceived to offer to monopolies. In all of
these ways, the entire society suffers when the rules governing an
economy allow an imbalance to develop that limits competition and
allows markets to be dominated by a few large companies. Even on
an international scale, monopolies affect negotiations ranging from
climate change to foreign investments. The power of monopolistic
companies is both pervasive and damaging.
Standard economic theory informs us about the sources of monop-
olies. Samuelson and Marks (2003: 365–366) discuss capital require-
ments in some industries that restrict entry to a very limited number
of large companies. Nicholson and Snyder (2007: 379) point to the
relevance of economies of scale, which are generally associated with
declining marginal costs of production. Ayers and Collinge (2003) em-
phasize the technological superiority of companies that gain a dom-
inant position in markets. Baumol and Willig (1981) note that lack
of substitutes and high sunk costs often form barriers to entry of
competitors. Blind (2004) analyzes how control of a natural resource
or network externalities can contribute to the formation of monopoly
power. There is a vast literature over several centuries that dwells
upon the role of political influence and rent-seeking in the creation
of a monopoly.
A particularly interesting aspect of a monopoly is the barrier to
entry. Anything that restricts (socially beneficial) competition is a bar-
rier to entry. Two types of barriers to entry have been frequently
discussed by other authors: structural and strategic (Geroski and
Jacquemin 1990). Structural barriers consist of relatively fixed con-
ditions related to costs and technologies, such as scale economies,
sunk costs, high capital costs, and product differentiation. Strategic
1137How Procurement Policies Promote Monopolies
barriers are erected by incumbent firms in the form of limit pricing,
predatory pricing, patents and other intellectual property, and other
actions taken to block competition. Some barriers that seem to be
structural are actually strategic because they are based on the conduct
of incumbent firms (Kotsios 2010).
A third type of barrier consists of regulatory barriers put in place
by governments (Geroski 1991; Parker and Stead 1991; Church and
Ware 2000; OECD 2005; Bitzenis 2009). Regulatory barriers can be
divided into three categories. The first one consists of restrictions on
production created through licensing requirements. The second group
involves international trade. Tariffs, import quotas, dumping (selling
surplus goods below cost), price fixing, subsidies, and tax exemptions
are all tools that can help one company gain an advantage over com-
petitors. Governments may also bias the market by making loans to
specific firms as part of a policy to protect domestic industry against
foreign competitors.
The third category of regulatory barriers consists of laws or poli-
cies that practically favor some firms over others even if the rules are
facially neutral. This article is an investigation of one type of barrier
within the third category. The focus here is on the understudied phe-
nomenon of public procurement and the social and economic effects
of how it is managed. The evidence produced here reveals huge dis-
tributional consequences of the design of tender and bid procedures
in India. Those procedures favor large firms over smaller ones by
erecting unnecessarily difficult eligibility criteria that firms must meet
even to apply.
I study select tender documents in transportation projects: roads,
highways, bridges, and civil construction. Transportation is a sector
that has been deemed “rent thick” because there are various sources
of unearned income associated with corruption in the contract pro-
cess and with the real estate aspects of this sector (Gandhi and Walton
2012: 12). As a result, this sector attracts large, politically connected,
private firms that hope to participate in the massive volume of work
and are often more interested in political kickbacks and the locational,
rent-generating aspects of projects than in the actual performance
of construction work. The procurement process effectively excludes

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT