How do Corporate Venture Capitalists do Deals? An Exploration of Corporate Investment Practices

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/sej.1178
Date01 December 2014
AuthorVangelis Souitaris,Stefania Zerbinati
Published date01 December 2014
HOW DO CORPORATE VENTURE CAPITALISTS
DO DEALS? AN EXPLORATION OF
CORPORATE INVESTMENT PRACTICES
VANGELIS SOUITARIS1,2* and STEFANIA ZERBINATI1
1Cass Business School, City University London, London, United Kingdom
2LUISS University, Rome, Italy
How do corporate venture capitalists (CVCs) do deals? Conversations with CVCs suggest that
the putative view of venture capital investing is incomplete. We draw on 13 cases of CVC
programs to document eight ‘corporate investment practices’ that are unique to CVCs. These
practices reflect pressureon the CVC units for strategic fit and engagement with the corporation
and also an opportunity to utilize parental resources. We then show that CVCs vary their
emphasis on corporate investment practices, diverging into two distinct investment logics,
‘integrated’versus ‘arm’s-length.’ Focus of isomorphism on internal versus external stakehold-
ers explains the emergence of the two logics. Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management Society.
‘We have one limited partner in our fund and we’ve
got to make sure we keep them happy, and that is
very different to an independent VC.’(K1, Kappa).
INTRODUCTION
Corporate venture capital (CVC) is defined as minor-
ity equity investments by established corporations in
privately held entrepreneurial ventures (Dushnitsky,
2012). CVC represents an important and growing
source of capital for entrepreneurs. Whereas inde-
pendent venture capital (VC) funds declined during
the 2000 to 2010 decade (Ghalbouni and Rouzies,
2010), corporate venture capital has shown an
upswing. As CVC activity has grown since 2005,
so has academic interest in the phenomenon
(Dushnitsky 2012; Hill et al., 2009; Keil, Autio, and
George, 2008; Maula, 2007). This study documents
and explains aspects of the CVC investment process
that diverge from standard practices of independent
venture capitalists (VCs).
The venture capital literature identified a series of
stages within a VC deal, such as deal origination,
screening, and structuring (Wright and Robbie,
1998; Gompers and Lerner, 2004; Fried and Hisrich,
1994; Tyebjee and Bruno, 1984), and then described
and explained specific practices within each stage,
such as syndication and staging (e.g., Gompers and
Lerner, 2004). We argue that the current theory,
framed around independent VCs, is not well suited
to fully explain the investment practices of CVCs for
two reasons: first, CVC units typically have a single,
dominant, limited partner, who owns the unit and
provides all the funds (the parent corporation).
Instead, independent VCs typically raise a fund from
multiple, nondominant, limited partners. Second, the
limited partner of CVC units (a corporation) typi-
cally seeks both financial and strategic benefits.
In contrast, the limited partners of independent VCs
are investors typically interested only in financial
returns. More broadly, since corporate ventures
differ in their practices from independent ventures
(Narayanan, Yang, and Zahra, 2009; Shrader and
Simon, 1997), we expect CVC investment practices
Keywords: corporate venture capital; investment practices;
focus of isomorphism; institutional logics
*Correspondence to: VangelisSouitaris, Cass Business School,
City University London, 106 Bunhill Row,London EC1Y 8TZ,
U.K. E-mail: v.souitaris@city.ac.uk
bs_bs_banner
Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal
Strat. Entrepreneurship J., 8: 321–348 (2014)
Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com). DOI: 10.1002/sej.1178
Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management Society
to differ from the documented practices of indepen-
dent VCs.
The recently emerged CVC literature has investi-
gated the applicability of broad structural features of
the ‘VC model’ (e.g., staging and compensation) to
CVCs (Dushnitsky and Shapira, 2010; Hill et al.,
2009; Maula, Autio, and Murray, 2005).Yet, we still
do not know if there are fine-grained practice differ-
ences between VCs and CVCs in the way they gen-
erate, screen, evaluate, approve, and monitor deals
(Hill et al., 2009).
Using a multiple case study design, we empiri-
cally derive and explain eight ‘corporate investment
practices’ that are unique to CVCs. Our intensive
data collection effort took place over a decade and
included two sets of data. We conducted six case
studies in 2002 and seven in 2011–12 to ensure that
our results were broadly replicable across two
temporal ‘waves’ of CVC. The dataset includes 45
interviews with 23 senior CVC executives, com-
plemented by archival data and independent expert
validation.
Our results point out that corporate investment
practices reflect parental pressure on CVC units to
secure strategic fit for their investments and to
engage with the other divisions of the corporation.
Corporate investment practices also reflect an oppor-
tunity to utilize valuable corporate resources and
capabilities. Moreover, we observed varying degrees
of emphasis on corporate investment practices
among CVCs, suggesting the emergence of two dis-
tinct investment logics: ‘integrated’ versus ‘arm’s-
length’ toward the corporate parent. Programs that
aligned with the norms of the parent (internal focus
of isomorphism) followed an integrated investment
logic. In contrast, programs that aligned with the
norms of the VC industry (external focus of isomor-
phism) followed an arm’s-length logic.
Our article makes three contributions. First, we
extend the venture capital literature by documenting
and explaining investment practices that are unique
to CVCs. Second, we contribute to the CVC litera-
ture by advancing a new typology of corporate inves-
tors (integrated versus arm’s-length toward the
parent). We elaborate on the concepts of CVC
autonomy and integration by specifying a bundle of
associated investment practices. For instance, ‘inte-
grated’ CVC programs utilize, to a higher extent,
investment practices, such as corporate referrals,
screening deals for strategic potential, and linking
the venture with the parent. Third, we contribute to
institutional theory by demonstrating an alternative
mechanism of how multiple logics emerge.1We
show that focus of isomorphism to different stake-
holders (Souitaris, Zerbinati, and Liu, 2012) can lead
to the emergence of multiple logics in a field and to
variation of practice.
THEORETICAL OVERVIEW
This is an inductive study to explore the investment
practices of CVCs. We developed a model using an
iterative process between data and pertinent litera-
ture. We begin with an overview of the literatures
that we consulted either before or during the course
of the study, which then informed our emerging find-
ings (Pratt, 2008; Suddaby, 2006).
Venture capital investing
The venture capital literature revealed a multistage
investment process: the stages include deal origina-
tion, screening, evaluation and due diligence, appro-
val and structuring, monitoring and value adding,
and investment realization (Wright and Robbie,
1998; Gompers and Lerner 2004; Fried and Hisrich,
1994; Tyebjee and Bruno, 1984).
Variousauthors documented specific VC practices
within each deal stage. For example, to generate
deals, VCs rely heavily on referrals from other VCs
and business associates (Fiet, 1995). Referrals are
used because they can reduce information asymme-
try and adverse selection; namely, the VC’s inability
to predict the manager’s performance prior to deal
completion (Amit, Glosten, and Muller, 1990). To
evaluate deals, VCs rely on criteria, such as market
potential, the quality of the team, and the probability
of a successful exit (Fried and Hisrich, 1994; Petty
and Gruber, 2011). More recently, much attention
has been devoted to agency theory arguments to
explain the practices of syndication, staging, and
performance-based compensation (Gompers and
Lerner, 2004).
This literature, which is biased toward indepen-
dent VCs, is relevant, but it does not fully consider
and explain the investment practices of CVCs. CVCs
are a distinct class of VCs because they typically
1We complement existing recognized mechanisms, such as
critical events (Nigam and Ocasio, 2010), structural changes
(Dunn and Jones, 2010), and institutional entrepreneurship
(Greenwood and Suddaby, 2006).
322 V. Souitaris and S. Zerbinati
Copyright © 2014 Strategic Management Society Strat. Entrepreneurship J.,8: 321–348 (2014)
DOI: 10.1002/sej

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT