How Do Balanced Budget Rules Impact Fiscal Performance Based On Revenue Structure?: Evidence From U.S. States

AuthorSungchan Kim,Soyoung Park
Published date01 June 2022
Date01 June 2022
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0160323X221094805
Subject MatterOriginal Research General Interest Articles
How Do Balanced Budget Rules
Impact Fiscal Performance
Based On Revenue Structure?:
Evidence From U.S. States
Sungchan Kim
1
and Soyoung Park
2
Abstract
Revenue condition needs to be considered in the design of balanced budget rules (BBRs), because
revenue stream, which varies across state governments, is an important factor in balancing the bud-
get. Also, revenue factors may inf‌luence state responses to economic crises through the employ-
ment of BBRs.Thus, this study examines the inf‌luence of BBRs on statesf‌iscal performance
depending on revenue structure using a panel data set from 1997 to 2016. The results demonstrate
that the strongest BBRs are effective in reducing def‌icit shocks, although this amplif‌ies f‌iscal volatil-
ity. However, the weakest BBRs play a role in stabilizing volatility. Considering revenue structure, if a
state government is concerned about def‌icit shocks, it would do well to adopt the strongest BBRs,
with lower levels of own-source revenue. Conversely, if a state government wishes to pursue f‌iscal
stabilization, it should adopt the weakest BBRs, with lower levels of own-source revenue and less
diversif‌ied source.
Keywords
balanced budget rules (BBRs), stringency of BBRs, f‌iscal performance, revenue context, f‌iscal
discretion
Introduction
Concerns about f‌iscal discipline at the state
level are signif‌icant, particularly during eco-
nomic downturns. Fiscal rules are considered
a form of f‌iscal discipline, helping to maintain
f‌iscal soundness. In the U.S., balanced budget
rules (BBRs) as a form of f‌iscal discipline
tend to compel state governments to engage in
procyclical policies involving budget cuts or
tax increases in response to a f‌iscal crisis.
State governments in the U.S. cut services and
reduced assistance payments during the most
recent recession, which began in 2007. This is
because BBRs prevent states from spending
when they have def‌icits, and indeed states
should spend based upon anticipated revenue.
Under BBRs, policy makers are constrained in
making budgetary decisions. Essentially,
1
Department of Public administration, Catholic University
of Korea, Bucheon, South Korea
2
Department of Public administration, Incheon National
University Incheon, Incheon, South Korea
Corresponding Author:
Soyoung Park, Department of Public administration,
Incheon National University Incheon, songdo yeonsu gu,
Incheon 22012, South Korea.
Email: soyoungp@inu.ac.kr
Original Research General Interest Articles
State and Local Government Review
2022, Vol. 54(2) 146-164
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0160323X221094805
journals.sagepub.com/home/slg
policy makers must decide whether to cut ser-
vices and/or increase taxes.
However, whether these institutional con-
straints lead to eff‌icient responses to f‌iscal
shocks or economic crises, ensuring f‌iscal
soundness through the adjustment of f‌iscal
policy, remains an open question. Several
scholars have argued that f‌iscal discipline may
cause a decline in average budget def‌icits
(Alesina and Perotti 1996), while other scholars
have argued that governments with such con-
straints are less likely to respond quickly to eco-
nomic shocks (Poterba 1994). For example,
Poterba (1994) found that more stringent
BBRs, such as no-def‌icit carryoverrules,
prevent states from adjusting their f‌iscal policy
in a f‌inancial crisis. In terms of budgetary con-
straints related to f‌iscal discipline, it is neces-
sary to explore whether these constraints lead
to effective budgetary responses in practice
across both states and time periods.
The impact of BBRs on f‌iscal policies has
been more extensively examined relative to
their strictness (Alt and Lowry 1994;
Endersby and Towle 1997; Hoover and
Pecorino 2005). However, few studies have
examined how the impacts differ depending
on revenue condition. Revenue condition must
be considered in the design of BBRs, because
revenue stream, which varies across state gov-
ernments, is an important factor in balancing
the budget. Revenue factors may inf‌luence
state responses to economic crises through the
employment of BBRs. The ability of states to
respond to f‌iscal crises will likely be affected
if they have f‌iscal restrictions relative to their
revenue condition. Thus, the purpose of this
study is to examine how BBRs impact f‌iscal
performance depending on the revenue condi-
tion of state governments. Specif‌ically, this
research will measure revenue condition using
revenue diversity, revenue elasticity, and level
of own-source revenue. Using a panel data set
from 1997 to 2016, this paper will investigate
the inf‌luence of BBRs on def‌icit shocks and
expenditure volatility depending on the
revenue condition of state governments.
The article is structured as follows. The next
section provides a brief review of the literature
on BBRs and tax structure, focusing on
revenue elasticity and revenue diversif‌ication.
We then explain variables and methods and
provide our empirical f‌indings. Finally, the
study offers concluding remarks.
Literature Review
BBRs and their Impact
All state governments except Vermont employ
BBRs. There are four types of BBRs, which
are as follows: (1) a governor must submit a
balanced budget to the legislature; (2) the legis-
lature must pass a balanced budget; (3) the gov-
ernor must sign a balanced budget; and (4) a
def‌icit cannot be carried over into the next
f‌iscal year (NASBO 2008; Poterba 1996).
Fatás and Mihov (2006) argued that the
degree and form of BBRs are related to the
phase of the budget process and associated
strictness. The f‌irst two forms are considered
weaker; neither imposes f‌iscal discipline at the
end of the f‌iscal year (Bohn and Inman 1996).
The remaining two forms proceed to the
ex-ante budget. Among the four categories, pro-
hibiting states from carrying over a def‌icit is
considered the most stringent form (Alesina
and Bayoumi 1996; Bohn and Inman 1996).
According to Bohn and Inman (1996), tight
end-of-year, higher-level, legal-based balanced
budget requirements play a signif‌icant role as
a constraint, while softlimitations applying
only to the beginning-of-the-year balance are
not considered effective constraints. State gov-
ernments adopt different conditions for BBRs.
Regarding the impacts of BBRs, Hou and
Smith (2006) explained that BBRs serve as an
effective tool for curbing state expenditures
and maintaining a balanced budget. Kudrin
and Sokolov (2017) also found that BBRs
reduce debt levels and may also increase
reserves. Schakel, Wu, and Jeurissen (2018)
revealed that BBRs lead to lower expenditures
and may control public spending through
f‌iscal rules. However, Costello, Petacchi, and
Weber (2017) demonstrated the probability of
BBRsnegative long-term effects on f‌iscal
soundness. In that study, governments sold
public assets to their own budget as well as
Kim and Park 147

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT