How Could the South Respond to Secular Stagnation in the North?

Date01 February 2017
AuthorJoerg Mayer
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12389
Published date01 February 2017
How Could the South Respond to Secular
Stagnation in the North?
Joerg Mayer
DGDS, UNCTAD, Geneva, Switzerland
1. INTRODUCTION
SEVEN years after the onset of the global financial crisis, world economic growth
remains significantly slower than before the crisis. Many developed countries continue
to lack robust demand growth and experience inflation significantly below targeted rates,
despite several years of accommodative monetary policy, improved financial conditions and
some relaxation of fiscal consolidation. Developing countries maintained rapid growth up to
201011 through the adoption of countercyclical policies, which raised domestic demand and
mitigated declining growth stimuli from the external economic environment. However, these
policies have been gradually unwound as many developing countries have experienced pres-
sure on domestic prices or trade balances that could be contained only by accepting lower
domestic-demand growth. The emphasis of the development literature on the importance of
developed-country growth for developing-country growth indicates that developing countries
may experience a progressive downward slide of growth if the lack of aggregate demand in
developed countries persists.
Concerns that economic growth in developed countries will remain weak for a protracted
period of time have been summarised as ‘secular stagnation’, that is an extended period of
low growth reflecting persistently weak demand that could turn into stagnation because
weak actual output growth reinforces the erosion of potential output growth. There is no
agreement as to whether the current economic situation in developed countries actually
reflects secular stagnation (for discussion see, e.g. Teulings and Baldwin, 2014), because
considerable unevenness across countries’ growth performance has emerged. Yet, the mere
risk of protracted subdued demand growth in developed countries and the spillover effects
of policies that they may adopt to address this phenomenon provide enough reason for
developing countries to consider a response to diminished prospects for export-led growth.
The paper’s main contributions are its focus on the impact that secular stagnation may
have on developing countries’ growth prospects and its use of a unified framework focused
on an integrated treatment of trade, finance, investment and innovation and based on two tra-
ditions that emphasise the role of exports in economic growth. These are the growth model
based on the balance-of-payments constraint (Thirlwall, 1979), which underlines the relat ion-
ship between imports and exports in the growth process, and the model of cumulative causa-
tion (Myrdal, 1957; Kaldor, 1970), which emphasises the positive association betwee n growth
of a country’s GDP and that of its manufacturing sector.
The paper’s main argument is that concerns raised by models emphasising the balance-of-
payments constraint on developing countries’ growth prospects are well founded, albeit less
serious than the simplest versions of the model would imply. Changing assumptions to allow
for cumulative-causation forces from domestic-demand growth and relative price effects indi-
cate that developing countries can maintain rapid growth by compensating for lower export
growth by faster domestic-demand growth, provided that they can also reduce the income
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
314
The World Economy (2017)
doi: 10.1111/twec.12389
The World Economy
elasticity of import demand. Achieving this requires changing policies towards a focus on
investment that moves the composition of domestic production closer to the emerging
composition of domestic demand and emphasises sectors that are sufficiently large to enjoy
cumulative-causation effects. Such investment should be accompanied by incomes policy and
capital-account management, as well as supply-side policies to strengthen innovation capacity.
Drawing down excessive foreign-exchange reserves or obtaining concessionary loans from
development banks could provide the financing for capital-goods imports that some develop-
ing countries may require. Resource-based economies will find growth rebalancing more
challenging than those that have developed manufacturing during periods of export-led
growth. Small countries may require further growth support from enhanced SouthSouth inte-
gration. Rebalancing developing countries’ growth strategies will be complicated if developed
countries continue addressing the risk of secular stagnation by relying on monetary expansion
and/or if their policies involve shifting the composition of their aggregate demand towards a
greater importance of external demand.
The next section discusses the risk of secular stagnation in developed countries, its poten-
tial reasons and attendant policy options. Section 3 examines the relationship between devel-
oped-country and developing-country growth from the perspective of growth models and
combines two demand-oriented models to consider the channels through which this relation-
ship works. Section 4 discusses policy responses by developing countries, and Section 5
concludes.
2. THE RISK OF SECULAR STAGNATION IN DEVELOPED COUNTRIES
The hypothesis of ‘secular stagnation’ describes the risk that very sluggish economic
growth becomes the new norm in developed countries because their traditional macroecon-
omic toolkit, and especially monetary policy, becomes ineffective (Krugman, 2014a;
Summers, 2014a, 2014b).
1
It asserts that the financial crisis of 200708 was a second-order
event and that the main culprit for the slow recovery from the crisis has been a decade-long
tendency of inadequate aggregate demand growth.
2
The United States has addressed the
resulting adverse effects on output growth by successive waves of accommodative monetary
1
The term ‘secular stagnation’ was coined by Hansen (1939) who worried that the United States was
facing slowing demographic and labour-force growth combined with constraints on farmland expansion
that would generate under-investment and aggregate demand deficiency that would cause economic
growth to decline to very slow rates. While fiscal expansion related to the Second World War and accel-
erated population growth during the 1950s prevented Hansen’s concern to materialise, the hypothesis
that global economic recovery over the past seven years has been held back by deficient aggregate
demand has revived interest in this issue. For a review on the diagnosis, causes and possible remedies of
secular stagnation, see, for example, Teulings and Baldwin (2014).
2
IMF (2014) considers the period of secular stagnation to have begun in the mid-1980s, when real
interest rates in developed countries started to decline following the adoption of disinflationary policies
in these countries. However, the mid-1980s also mark the beginning of the long-run decline of the wage
share in developed countries (ILO, 2015). Disinflationary policies may be at the origin of this decline as
they became theoretically justifiable following the growing attention given during the 1970s and 1980s
to new classical macroeconomics that, as opposed to Keynesian economics, asserts that only the aggre-
gate price level and labour market flexibility, and not aggregate demand, have an impact on output and
employment growth.
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
POSSIBLE RESPONSES TO SECULAR STAGNATION 315

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT