Hoarding the Herd: The Convenience of Productive Stocks

AuthorAtle Oglend,Frank Asche,Dengjun Zhang
Date01 July 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.21679
Published date01 July 2015
HOARDING THE HERD:THE CONVENIENCE OF
PRODUCTIVE STOCKS
FRANK ASCHE, ATLE OGLEND* and DENGJUN ZHANG
This paper investigates the convenience yield that emerges in markets with productive stocks.
We isolate the economic fundamentals giving rise to the yield, and show how these map to the
empirical convenience yield measure. A model for price dynamics is derived from an economic
model for optimal stock levels. We show how the price process reduces to a simple nonlinear
rstorder Markov process. The model is estimated for the Norwegian market for farmed salmon
by Generalized Methods of Moments, where stock growth is approximated by seawater
temperature. Our estimation result supports the theorized role of stock growth as a convenience
yield component. Our results are relevant for the functioning of futures markets for
commodities such as sh and other animal production where systematic stock growth affects
the term structure. © 2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 35:679694, 2015
1. INTRODUCTION
This paper shows that productive storage or stocks lead to the inverted termstructure
generally associated with a convenience yield. This is an important factor in most forms of
animal production, where stocks are fed and are therefore growing. The convenience yield
depends on both expected growth and price, in addition to the covariance between growth
and prices. We demonstrate the empirical relevance of this convenience yield by analyzing the
market for farmed salmon, including the relativity new futures market for salmon.
The convenience yield was rst introduced to account for the observation that agents in
commodity markets held stocks even when prices for future delivery where lower than current
prices (Brennan, 1958; Kaldor, 1939; Working, 1948, 1949). The convenience yield can be
dened as an incremental economic benet of holding stocks outside of the spread between
futures and spot prices, adjusted for the full carrying cost (interest, warehousing, insurance
etc.). Several economic factors have been proposed to account for such an economic benet.
Deaton and Laroque (1992) suggest that when the commodity is scarce, stocks have an
additional value as insurance against future stockouts. The convenience yield is then the
result of the real option value of holding stocks (Heaney, 2002; Litzenberger &
Rabinowitz, 1995; Routledge, Duane, & Chester, 2000). It is also argued that producers
requiring primary commodities as inputs might sit on stocks to avoid costly changes in
production schedules or complete shut downs (Considine & Larson, 2001; Litzenberger &
Rabinowitz, 1995). This will imbue stocks with a convenience yield as derived demand
Frank Asche (Professor), Atle Oglend (Associate Professor), and Dengjun Zhang (Post doc.) are collocated at
the Department of Industrial Economics, University of Stavanger, Stavanger, Norway. We would like to thank
the Norwegian Research Council for nancial support.
*Correspondence author, Department of Industrial Economics, University of Stavanger, 4036 Stavanger, Norway.
Tel: þ4741446414, Fax: þ4751931750, email: atle.oglend@uis.no
Received September 2013; Accepted March 2014
The Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 35, No. 7, 679694 (2015)
© 2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Published online 22 April 2014 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com).
DOI: 10.1002/fut.21679
becomes highly inelastic when scarcity increases. These explanations originate from
uncertainty regarding future availability, and the convenience yield is essentially the result
of hoarding behavior, although the behavior can be purely economically motivated. Other
explanations suggest that the convenience yield might be the result of data aggregation issues
(Benirschka & Binkley, 1995; Brennan, Williams, & Wright, 1997; Wright & Williams, 1989).
Here, the observed convenience yield is the result of prices being averaged across different
locations and grades. It is an artifact of the data, whereby transportation costs or quality
differences are not properly accounted for when comparing prices. In an examination of the
United States corn market, Frechete and Fackler (1999) fails to nd empirical support for this
hypothesis. In the traditional nancial interpretation, which can be tracked back to Keynes
(1930), a backwarded futures market that would give the appearance of a convenience yield is
the result of a necessary risk compensation to holders of futures contracts. In practice, risk
compensation results in a spot price above the futures prices and a generally downward
sloping futures curve. This explanation does not require any marginal economic beneton
stockkeeping, but is the result of riskaverse agents in the futures market.
Looking beyond specic causes, the market effects of the convenience yield are well
known. A high convenience yield is associated with low stocks, price spiking, high price
volatility, and an inverted term structure of futures prices. The hoardinglike behavior
associated with a convenience yield reduces the market elasticity of demand and leads to
increasing prices as the commodity is effectively removed from the normal ow of the market.
Volatility increases as the intertemporal smoothing function of storage is reduced. Since the
convenience yield varies with stock levels, it is endogenous to the market, while
simultaneously affecting the behavior of individual market agents. Hence, the convenience
yield is an indicator of scarcity and future security of supply and plays a relevant informational
role in price discovery.
The exact convenience yield is generally thought of as a latent variable. In empirical
analysis, it is measured by the spread between a futures price and the spot price, adjusted for
carrying costs and the interest rate. If this spread is negative, suggesting an economic loss from
keeping stocks, it is argued that a convenience yield is present. Much work has been done on
investigating the economic signicance of this convenience yield and its consistency with
economic theory. Ng and Pirrong (1994) and Nielsen and Schwartz (2004) show that a high
convenience yield is associated with higher spot price volatility. Casassus and CollinDufresne
(2005) nd a strong spot price dependence of the convenience yield for crude oil, copper, gold,
and silver. Chiou Wei and Zhu (2006) show that for natural gas the convenience yield is
economically signicant, at 35% of the spot price on average, and that it varies in a manner
consistent with economic theory. In agricultural markets, Fama and French (1987) show that
the convenience yield has considerable variability, in addition to a seasonality. More recently,
Gorton, Hayashi, and Rouwenhorst, (2013) investigate 31 commodities using futures and
physical inventory data from 1969 to 2006. They nd that the convenience yield is decreasing
and nonlinear in inventories. Related to a convenience yield, Peterson and Tomek (2005)
demonstrate how prices of storable crops become increasingly volatile and rightskewed as one
approaches harvest time. Similarly, Lence and Hayenga (2001) show that a high current spot
price is associated with low stocks and a high convenience yield. The convenience yield is also
recognized as relevant when pricing commodity based contingent claims, such as in the
futures pricing model of Gibson and Schwartz (1990). Although the adjusted basis is the
conventional empirical measure of a convenience yield, it does not by itself provide any insight
into how and what relevant economic fundamentals generate it.
A feature that has not received much attention is that a convenience yield can emerge
when stocks grow in storagethat is, when stocks are productive. If stocks grow, as is typical
in animal production, there is a direct economic benet from keeping stocks. To allow for
680 Asche, Oglend, and Zhang

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT