Historical Inequality at the Grassroots: Local Public Goods in an Indian District, 1905–2011

Published date01 October 2023
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00104140231152767
AuthorAlexander Lee
Date01 October 2023
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Comparative Political Studies
2023, Vol. 56(12) 18241857
© The Author(s) 2023
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00104140231152767
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Historical Inequality at
the Grassroots: Local
Public Goods in an Indian
District, 19052011
Alexander Lee
1,
Abstract
How do historical inequalities inf‌luence modern public goods provision? This
paper analyses a new panel dataset of local public goods provision in a single
North Indian district with observations at the village-decade level going back
to 1905 and detailed information on colonial land tenure institutions and
demographics. The presence of large colonial landowners is positively as-
sociated with rural public goods provision when the landlord was resident in
the early 20th century and has a null effect when the landlord was an absentee.
Villages inhabited or owned by upper castes had an advantage in the colonial
and immediate post-independence eras, but not afterward. The results
suggest that within unequal societies, economic and status inequalities can
have positive effects on public goods provision when they link elites to
extralocal decision-makers.
Keywords
historical legacies, state capacity, public goods
1
University of Rochester, Rochester, NY, USA
Thanks to Ha Nguyen, Bill Ktepi, Prambod Manohar, Melanie Wu, Philippe Maas, Natasha Abrol
and especially JB Venkatesh for excellent research assistance and Jack Paine, Anderson Frey,
Gretchen Helmke and attendees at the Southern and American Political Science Associations
annual meetings for comments. Replication data are available at the CPS dataverse https://doi.
org/10.7910/DVN/VSRNFS
Corresponding Author:
Alexander Lee, University of Rochester, Harkness Hall, Rochester, NY 14627, USA.
Email: alexander.mark.lee@rochester.edu
Introduction
In the past two decades, there has been an explosion of literature on the long-
term effects of historical institutions on economic development and public
goods provision (Acemoglu et al., 2002;Dasgupta, 2018;Dell, 2010;Iyer,
2010;Sellars & Alix-Garcia, 2018;Sokoloff & Engerman, 2000). Much of
this literature focuses on the causes of persistent institutional arrangements
that raise levels of economic inequality or empower elite groups. Critical
junctures, in this formulation, are critical because they determine the amount
of social power the elite can wield. These historical arguments are important
because a common claim in the literature on the political economy of public
goods provision is that higher levels of social inequality, or the presence of
institutions that strengthen inequality and social groups that benef‌it from it, are
associated with lower levels of public goods provision (Acemoglu et al., 2014;
Anderson et al., 2015;Baldwin & Huber, 2010;Mattingly, 2016;Shami,
2012;Suryanarayan, 2017). Such inequalities are thought to weaken the
potential for local collective action and redistributive taxation to fund public
goods provision. Why should elites pay a disproportionate share of costs to
fund public goods that may in the long run undermine their social position?
There is, however, an alternative theoretical logic. While powerful local
elites may undermine local collective action, they may be in a stronger
position than the poor to lobby with extralocal elites to fund public goods in
their area and may also have suff‌icient private investments in their community
to overcome incentives to free ride (Olson, 1971). If this lobbying effect
dominates the collective action effect, more inequality in status and land
would be associated with higher levels of public goods provision at the local
level, though not necessarily at the social level (Baldwin, 2019;Dell, 2010;
Kustov & Pardelli, 2018;Lee, 2018). This effect should be most apparent in
the communities where elites actually live, and where they can thus personally
benef‌it from goods that improve human capital and from the prestige rents that
accrue to successful community advocates (Tsai, 2007).
The ability of the persistence literature to test this alternative logic is
limited by two analytical shortcuts. Firstly, the unit of analysis is often distinct
from the unit of treatment, either because of change in the structure of units
over time or the unavailability of disaggregated data; processes that occur at
the local or even individual level are measured either at the state or district
levels (Banerjee & Iyer, 2005;Banerjee & Somanathan, 2007;Chaudhary,
2009;Iversen et al., 2013;Lee, 2019b). Results may vary widely based on the
level of aggregation, particularly when the units of aggregation themselves are
correlated with preexisting geographical conditions and subsequent historical
events. Secondly, measurements of the outcome of interest may not be
available for a long part of the period between the historical treatment and the
present day, making it impossible to assess changes in effect size over time. In
Lee 1825
fact, perhaps the most common design is cross-sectional, with only suggestive
evidence of whether or how an institutions effect persisted over the decades
(or, sometimes, millennia) between treatment and measurement.
Given its deep-seated social and economic inequalities, India has seen
studies of both public goods provision and historical institutions. For instance,
in some areas, the colonial state transferred land tenure rights to a few large
landlords; a policy thought to be associated with lower levels of local public
goods provision and agricultural investment (Banerjee & Iyer, 2005).
1
The
rankedsocial differences characteristic of the caste system are also widely
thought important in shaping political patterns (Anderson et al., 2015;
Banerjee & Somanathan, 2007;Chaudhary, 2009;Suryanarayan, 2017;
Waring & Bell, 2013) with status inequality associated with local levels of
public goods provision.
This paper analyses a new dataset of public goods outcomes and historical
institutions in a single district in the North Indian state of Uttar Pradesh (UP),
Agra. The unit of measurement is the village-year, the basic level at which
public goods are assigned. For many villages, it includes detailed information
on the structure of landholding in the late colonial era, collected from un-
published colonial records from the local archives. These are supplemented
with colonial census data, which gives detailed information of local caste and
occupational breakdowns in the late colonial period. These data on local
conditions supplement panel data on the provision of local public goods in
each village that was collected (roughly) every decade from 1905 to 2011. The
data is thus complementary to studies focused on individual villages over time
such as Lanjouw, Stern (1998) and broader accounts of rural UPs historical
evolution such as Metcalf (1979).
The data show only very limited support for existing hypotheses about the
effects of historical inequality. Ownership of the village by a single landlord in
colonial times is not associated with lower levels of public goods provision
than more fragmented ownership after conditioning on village population and
location, either today or in any previous historical period, even after con-
ditioning on a wide variety of spatial and environmental traits. In fact, villages
with a single colonial landlord were slightly more likely than other villages to
have high levels of public goods provision in the late 20th century, but only if
the landlord lived in the village. Villages owned by absentees, who had no
incentive to advocate for local public goods provision, are identical to non-
landlord villages, a f‌inding that is reminiscent of older arguments about the
negative effects of absentee landlordism on local social solidarity (Moore,
1966).
The effect of the presence of upper caste groups varies over time. The
presence of upper caste groups, either as a plurality of the population or as a
plurality of landowners, had a positive inf‌luence in the Colonial (19051951)
and Congress(195191) eras, when upper castes were overwhelmingly
1826 Comparative Political Studies 56(12)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT