Health subsidies, prevention and welfare

Published date01 December 2023
AuthorLuca Marchiori,Olivier Pierrard
Date01 December 2023
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12583
Received: 8 September 2021
|
Accepted: 1 March 2022
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12583
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Health subsidies, prevention and welfare
Luca Marchiori|Olivier Pierrard
Banque centrale du Luxembourg,
Luxembourg, Luxembourg
Correspondence
Luca Marchiori, Banque centrale du
Luxembourg, 2 boulevard Royal,
Luxembourg L2983, Luxembourg.
Email: luca.marchiori@bcl.lu
Abstract
People value healthy ageing but may underinvest in
healthimproving preventive care. This arises when
they ignore the beneficial effects of healthy ageing on
public health expenditures and hence on the tax
burden of future generations. This health externality
justifies public intervention. We build an overlapping
generations model with a government subsidizing
investment in health by the young generation and
paying the health care costs of the old generation. We
find that the welfaremaximizing subsidy rate depends
positively on the health externality and the size of
health care costs, and negatively on the discount factor.
The subsidy rate should therefore be high when
prevention is costeffective and when the population
is careless about the future. Moreover, the welfare
maximizing subsidy rate is lower than the health
maximizing rate but higher than the capital
maximizing rate. This underlines the tradeoff for a
policy maker between health and economy.
1|INTRODUCTION
In this paper, we focus on one type of positive health externality, namely that young agents
ignore that healthy ageing (lower morbidity) reduces publicly financed curative health care
costs and hence the tax burden on the next generation. From a welfare point of view, this leads
to a private underinvestment in preventive health care justifying public intervention like
subsidies to prevention. Using an overlapping generations (OLG) setup, we analytically derive
the optimal subsidy policy. Our results also underline the tradeoff between health and
economy faced by a policymaker.
Why is this question important? First, one challenge of the graying society is to maintain
older people in good health (see e.g., EC, 2007; WHO, 2015), which requires preventive health
J Public Econ Theory. 2023;25:13041336.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet1304
|
© 2022 Wiley Periodicals LLC
care measures to improve future health status (Musich et al., 2016). Using OECD data, Wang
(2018) finds that preventive health care is currently underprovided whereas curative health
care is overprovided. This suggests that a change in the relative price of caresfor example,
through more subsidies on preventioncould improve the allocation of health expenditures
between prevention and cures. Second, theabsolute value of theelasticity of curative costs
with respect to preventive actions may be large. Empirical studies show that prevention has a
considerable cost reducing effect by lowering morbidity, which again justifies the existence of
subsidization. Indeed, financial incentives may encourage healthy (e.g., dieting, physical
activity) or discourage unhealthy (e.g., smoking, alcohol) sustained behaviors and are found to
particularly support infrequent behaviors as vaccinations and screening (Mantzari et al., 2015;
Vlaev et al., 2019). Results on costsaving initiatives in the UK find that a return of 1.35 pounds
can be expected on every pound invested in flu vaccine or that screening is costsaving in the
short run for cervical cancer (below 5 years) and in the longer run for breast and colon cancer
(see WHO, 2014, for a review of these different studies).
1
Third, advanced countries spend
considerable resources on health. For instance, US national health expenditures as percent of
GDP increased from 5% in 1960% to 18% in 2015 (Catlin & Cowan, 2015). By 2028, US health
care should reach one fifth of the GDP. Although US has the highest health spending ratio
among developed countries, costs also exceed 10% in most European countries. One important
cost driver is the use of health care to live a longer healthy life, with costs proportionally larger
at older ages (WHO, 2018). Thus a costbenefit analysis of subsidy on preventive care matters
not only from a medical but also from a public finance point of view.
To study the theoretical effects of health subsidy, we use an OLG framework with
households living for two periods. When young, households make consumption/savings
choices and undertake private healthimproving medical expenses, in short health investments.
These investments enhance individuals' health at old age, which provides utility and lowers the
need for publicly financed health care. There are thus two types of capital in the model and
both contribute to raise utility when old. Investing in physical capital provides earnings and
thus utility from higher old age consumption. Health investments improve health capital and
raise utility from a better health status. However, in contrast to physical capital, health capital
involves an externality. Indeed, young households invest in health capital to raise utility, not
caring that higher health capital will also reduce publicly financed health care when old and
hence the tax rate on the next generation. There is thus a rationale for the government to
subsidize medical expenses. The government taxes labor income to finance subsidies on health
investments by the young and health care needs of the elderly. A subsidy policy therefore
affects the economy through different channels. First, for given private health expenditures, a
higher subsidy raises taxation and depresses disposable income. This is the direct cost channel.
Second, for a given disposable income, a higher subsidy spurs health investments at the
expense of savings and consumption. This is the health investment channel. Third, increased
prevention today improves health status tomorrow, which reduces publicly financed health
care costs of the elderly. This is the health externality channel. A strong health externality
1
In general, prevention influences both morbidity and mortality. It directly decreases health care costs by lowering
morbidity, but also indirectly increases them by delaying mortality, with people continuing to consume health care
during the additional years of life (usually spent in poor health). Grootjansvan Kampen et al. (2014) consider five
disease categories and show that in four out of five categories, prevention leads to health care savings without longevity
gains. Only prevention of highly fatal diseases (neoplasms) raises life expectancy and healthrelated costs.
MARCHIORI AND PIERRARD
|
1305
indicates that prevention is on average effective at reducing future costs or alternatively that
prevention only targets specific costsaving initiatives.
We look at the steady state effects of a health subsidy on (i) physical capital, (ii) health status and
(iii) welfare. We show that the subsidy rate maximizing welfare depends positively on the health
externality and the size of health care costs, and negatively on the discount factor. The welfare
maximizing subsidy must therefore be large when prevention is very effective at reducing costs and
whenthepubliccostofhealthisimportant.Itmustalsobelargewhenprivateagentsdonotcare
enough about the future. This latter result relates to the empirical literature (see for instance Wang &
Sloan, 2018) showing that when individuals have an important degree of present bias, they are less
likely to invest in health. We also find that the subsidy rate maximizing welfare is larger than the rate
maximizing physical capital, but lower than the rate maximizing health status. Indeed, maximizing
welfare means we need good health, since health enters in the utility, but also a large capital stock to
generate enough production and consumption. Maximizing only health implies that we accept high
taxes and low consumption to pay for a very generous policy. Maximizing only capital means that we
accept a less generous policy and poorer health to lower taxes and stimulate savings. This key
message from a prevention policytradeoff between health and growthis clearly robust to other
situations as for instance the containment policy in case of a pandemic (see, among many others,
Alvarez et al., 2020). To illustrate the theoretical findings,wepresentanumericalexamplebasedon
two advanced economies differing in the parameters of the health system structure. Moreover,
obtaining a full analytical characterization of the results obviously requires some specific modeling
choices. We therefore produce various numerical sensitivity analyzes and also discuss the
implications on our results of other types of health externalities (see Appendices A,C,D,andE).
Our paper relates to two branches of the health economics literature. One deals with
optimal health policy but disregards general equilibrium effects and macroeconomic
implications (Andersen & Bhattacharya, 2014; Cremer et al., 2012; Leroux et al., 2011)or
health externalities (Canta et al., 2016; Jack & Sheiner, 1997; Jaspersen & Richter, 2015). The
other one is concerned with the implications of health investments on the macroeconomy in
the presence of sideeffects of health capital but does not focus on optimal policy.
2
Several
studies examine how health spending lowers mortality and affects growth in developing
countries.
3
In Chakraborty (2004), public health investments raise longevity, which spurs
savings and raises the returns to human capital investment. In more wealthy countries, where
life expectancy is already high, health expenses increase more the quality of life than longevity.
Morbidity reduction may directly improve labor productivity (e.g., Fanti & Gori, 2011) and
some analyzes introduce both life expectancy and productivity effects (Kuhn & Prettner, 2016).
Only two other papers consider a health sideeffect describing how lower morbidity reduces
healthrelated costs, which has been empirically shown to be important (Grootjansvan
2
One exception is Atolia et al. (2021) who determine quantitatively the optimal combination of taxes and subsidies in a
neoclassical model and find that optimal subsidies increase along with the health externality on productivity. Our work
is complementary to theirs, as we find similar results (the optimal subsidy increases in the externality) using an
analytical approach and focusing on a different type of health externality.
3
These studies look at healthinduced longevity changes and are therefore also connected to a vast literature examining
the relationship between demographic factors and economic development. Many studies in this literature focus on the
implications of exogenous changes in longevity, reflecting, for example, policy changes, through capital accumulation
(Ito & Tabata, 2008) or through more complex mechanisms (like human capital accumulation or endogenous labor
supply, see Boucekkine et al., 2002; de la Croix & Licandro, 1999; Zhang et al., 2003). Other authors consider the effects
of endogenous life expectancy influenced by individual decisions (on health or education, see e.g., Blackburn &
Cipriani, 2002) or by aggregate variables (like environmental quality, see Balestra & Dottori, 2012).
1306
|
MARCHIORI AND PIERRARD

Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI

Get Started for Free

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT