Guidance on Abuse in Europe: The Continued Concern for Rivalry and a Competitive Structure

AuthorLiza Lovdahl Gormsen,Philip Marsden
Date01 December 2010
Published date01 December 2010
DOI10.1177/0003603X1005500408
Subject MatterArticle
Guidance on abuse in Europe:
The continued concern for rivalry
and a competitive structure
BYPHILIP MARSDEN*AND LIZA LOVDAHL GORMSEN**
Both the United States and the EU allegedly protect the competitive
process through an effects-based approach to the analysis of
exclusionary abuses. Importantly though, each jurisdiction starts from a
different end of the spectrum. The article finds that while U.S. antitrust
appears to protect the competitive process to enhance consumer welfare
in the form of allocative and productive efficiency, EU competition law
protects the structure of competition to protect rivalry. When applying
Article 102 TFEU, the European Commission and the courts rely on two
presumptions that hearken back to Ordoliberalism. The existence of
dominance creates a presumption of harm to the structure of
competition (foreclosure), and that harm to the structure of competition
in turn creates a presumption of likely harm to consumers
(anticompetitive foreclosure). These presumptions are apparent in case
law as well as the Commission’s Guidance Paper on Article 102. This
article concludes that despite having the same aim, there is still a trans-
Atlantic divide about how best to protect the competitive process.
THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN:Vol. 55, No. 4/Winter 2010 :875
* British Institute of International and Comparative Law.
** London School of Economics and King’s College London.
AUTHORS’ NOTE: This article develops themes raised in Philip Marsden, Monopoli-
zation: What is Behind the Trans-Atlantic Divide?, in CHALLENGES IN THE
ENFORCEMENT OF ARTICLE 82 (Federico Etro & Ioannis Kokkoris eds., 2010) by in
particular tracing further evidence of Ordoliberal thought in current enforcement practice
and case law.
© 2010 by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
I. INTRODUCTION
On either side of the Atlantic top enforcement officials have recently
stated that the aim of their prohibitions of monopolization and abuse
of dominance—Sherman Act section 2 and Article 102 of the Lisbon
Treaty (ex Article 82),1respectively—is to protect the competitive
process through an effects-based approach.2Indeed, over the past few
years, the two jurisdictions seem to have been coming closer together.
According to current Assistant Attorney General Christine
Varney,“[B]oth jurisdictions eschew per se and formulaic approaches,
and instead embrace effects-based analyses of single-firm conduct.”3
This was echoed by then-Competition Commissioner Neelie Kroes:
“An effects-based approach has also been central to our Article 82
[now Article 102] enforcement in recent years.”4
That said, each jurisdiction starts from a different end of the
spectrum, as Varney has emphasized:
There still may be some level of disconnect between the U.S. and the EC
in our fundamental attitudes—or underlying presumptions—about what
it means to protect the competitive process and how competition law best
achieves that objective.
. . . .
876 :THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN:Vol. 55, No. 4/Winter 2010
1The Lisbon Treaty came into force on December 1, 2009, and Article 82
EC was renumbered Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the Euro-
pean Union.
2Neelie Kroes, Competition Commissioner, Preliminary Thoughts on
Policy Review of Article 82, Speech to Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept.
23, 2005), available at http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do ?reference
=SPEECH/05/537&format=HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en;
Christine A. Varney, Assistant Attorney General, Striving for the Optimal Balance
in Antitrust Enforcement: Single-Firm Conduct, Antitrust Remedies, and
Procedural Fairness, Remarks Prepared for the Council on Foreign Relations 3
(Oct. 8, 2009), available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/speeches
/250814.htm.
3Varney, supra note 2, at 4.
4Neelie Kroes, Competition Commissioner, Exclusionary Abuses of
Dominance: The European Commission’s Enforcement Priorities, Speech to
Fordham Corporate Law Institute (Sept. 25, 2008), available at http://europa
.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/08/457&format
= HTML&aged=0&language=EN&guiLanguage=en .
[T]here still seems to be more scepticism in Europe than in the U.S. about
the generally procompetitive nature of price discounting and the impor-
tance of efficiencies.5
There is thus still a trans-Atlantic divide about what it means to
protect the competitive process and how best to do that. Both the
United States and the EU protect the competitive process
instrumentally, i.e. as a means to an end. However, the United States, in
our view, protects the competitive process to enhance consumer
welfare6in form of allocative and productive efficiency, whereas the EU
still protects a competitive structure to protect rivalry. It does this for
various stated ends, including economic freedom7and consumer
welfare,8even though these ends may conflict with each other.9In the
United States historically, we saw a similar concern for rivalry—rather
than mere economic efficiency—but then it was called “populism” or
“structuralism,” and it produced results that were very different from
those the authorities and courts have produced since the focus
changed, in the 1970s, to economic efficiency and consumer welfare.10
ABUSE OF DOMINANCE :877
5Varney, supra note 2, at 6.
6Reiter v. Sonotone Corp., 442 U.S. 330, 343 (1979); ROBERT BORK, THE
ANTITRUST PARADOX: A POLICY AT WAR WITH ITSELF 91, 427 (1993); Joseph Farrell
& Michael L. Katz, The Economics of Welfare Standards in Antitrust, 2 COMPETITION
POLYINTL1 (2006); Thomas O. Barnett & Hill B. Wellford, The DOJ’s Single-
Firm Conduct Report: Promoting Consumer Welfare Through Clearer Standards for
Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 2 GLOBAL COMPETITION POLY2 (2008); Christine A.
Varney, Vigorous Antitrust Enforcement in this Challenging Era, Remarks
prepared for the United States Chamber of Commerce 7 (May 12, 2009).
7Economic freedom means that the economic system should allow all
individuals the freedom to participate in the marketplace unimpaired by the
power of other companies.
8One common definition of consumer welfare is consumer surplus,
which is the aggregate measure of the surplus of all consumers. The surplus
of a given consumer is the difference between his or her valuation of a good
and the price he or she actually pays for it. See MASSIMO MOTTA, COMPETITION
POLICY: THEORYAND PRACTICE 18 (2004).
9Liza Lovdahl Gormsen, The Conflict between Economic Freedom and
Consumer Welfare in the Modernisation of Article 82 EC, 3 EUR. COMPETITION J.
329–31 (2007).
10 Liza Lovdahl Gormsen, The Parallels between the Harvard Structural
School and Article 82 EC and the Divergences between the Chicago and Post-Chicago

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT