Growth, intergenerational welfare, and environmental policies in an overlapping generations economy

Published date01 May 2018
Date01 May 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12371
REGULAR ARTICLE
Growth, intergenerational welfare, and
environmental policies in an overlapping
generations economy
Hsun Chu
1
|
Chu-chuan Cheng
2
|
Ching-chong Lai
3,4,5
1
Department of Economics, Tunghai
University, Taiwan
2
Department of Accounting, Feng Chia
University, Taiwan
3
Institute of Economics, Academia
Sinica, Taiwan
4
Department of Economics, National
Cheng Chi University, Taiwan
5
Institute of Economics, National Sun
Yat-Sen University, Taiwan
Correspondence
Hsun Chu, Department of Economics,
Tunghai University, No. 1727, Sec. 4,
Xitun Dist., Taiwan Boulevard, Taichung,
40704 Taiwan.
Email: hchu0824@gmail.com
Abstract
This paper examines the effects of the environmental tax
on long-run growth and intergenerational welfare in a dis-
crete-time overlapping generations (OLG) model. We
highlight that the role regarding how the environmental
tax revenues are distributed between the young or old
generations has important implications for the growth and
welfare effects. Our results indicate that raising the envi-
ronmental tax can exert different effects on the environ-
mental utility of the existing young and old generations,
implying an intergenerational welfare conflict of the envi-
ronmental policy. However, if tax revenues are distributed
appropriately, our numerical simulation shows that it is
possible for a higher environmental tax to improve the
welfare of all generations.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Externalities lie at the heart of environmental economics. These externalities are usually not only
intragenerationalpolluters affect currently living humans, but also intergenerationalthey impose
a cost on future generations. Environmental policies, therefore, should be responsible for internaliz-
ing both types of externalities. In this study, we examine the intertemporal welfare effects of the
environmental policies. We ask the following questions: What is the environmental policy impact
on the welfare of different generations? Does an intergenerational welfare conflict emerge from the
implementation of a tighter environmental policy? Is it possible for an environmental policy to
improve the welfare of all generations?
To address these questions, we construct a two-period overl apping generations (OLG) model
a
la Diamond (1965) featuring endogenous growth and environmental externalities. There are
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12371
844
|
©2017 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode Rev Dev Econ. 2018;22:844861.
multiple externalities in this model. First, in order to introduce endogenous growth, we consider
the capital externality
a la Romer (1986) and Lucas (1988) on the production side. Moreover, the
production process emits pollution leading to a deterioration in the environmental quality, which
consequently generates two types of environmental externalities. The first environmental externality
affects the individuals utility. As is obvious, a worse environment reduces peoples happiness. For
instance it can negatively affect peoples health or reduce their satisfaction with outdoor leisure.
The second environmental externality influences the firms productivity. A worse environment
harms workershealth, and bad air quality can accelerate the depreciation of equipment. These
facts indicate that a poor environment reduces the efficiency of the production process. Our speci-
fications that pollution negatively affects both the individualsutility and firmsproductivity are in
accordance with these observations.
1
A notable feature of our analysis is that we highlight the role of how the environmental tax rev-
enues are distributed between the young or old generations. This role has important implications
both for the growth and welfare effects of the environmental tax. For the growth effect, we show
that raising the environmental tax tends to stimulate economic growth when the tax revenues are
largely transferred to the young generation. The intuition is that tax revenues transferred to the old
generation are entirely consumed, while some part of the tax revenues transferred to the young
generation is used to accumulate physical capital, which is beneficial to growth. Accordingly, the
result of the positive growth effect of the environmental tax does not necessarily rely on the pres-
ence of an environmental externality in production.
With respect to the welfare effect of the environmental tax, our results characterize the inter-
generational welfare conflicts between the elderly and young, and between existing and future
generations. When the government raises the environmental tax, the environmental quality will
be improved, and at the same time it has an ambiguous effect on economic growth. For the
existing old generation who only lives in the current period, it does not have time to wait for
the improvement of the environmental quality, neither can it have time to enjoy a higher eco-
nomic growth. Therefore, its welfare is determined primarily by the rebates of tax revenues it
can receive. Obviously, the existing old generation will experience a welfare gain if a large por-
tion of tax revenues is transferred to the old generation. By contrast, for the existing young and
future generations, both the environment and economic growth matter for their welfare. In the
case where the environmental tax enhances growth, all generations (except the existing old gen-
eration) are able to experience a better environment and higher growth, which represents a defi-
nite welfare gain. In the case where the environmental tax depresses economic growth, the
welfare effect of the environmental tax becomes uncertain, but generations born in the very dis-
tant future will definitely lose because the growth effect plays a dominant role in evaluating their
welfare.
In a counterpart of this study, Bovenberg and Heijdra (1998) investigate the intergenerational
welfare effect of an environmental tax in an OLG model
a la Yaari (1965) and Blanchard
(1985).
2
Our results differ from theirs in several important respects. First, in their model, a wel-
fare gain from a better environment is identical among all existing generations regardless of
whether they are old or young. In our model, by contrast, raising the environmental tax bene fits
the environmental utility of existing young generations more than of existing old generations, by
virtue of the feature that existing old generations can hardly wait for the improvement of the envi-
ronment. Second, in their model, the existing (very) old generations certainly lose from raising
the environmental tax; as a consequence, a Pareto-improving environmental tax is not possible in
their model. In our model, the existing old generation may be better off if it receives adequate
rebates of tax revenues. Importantly, our result implies that a Pareto-improving environmental tax
CHU ET AL.
|
845

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT