Group Buying Commitment and Sellers’ Competitive Advantages

Date01 March 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12000
Published date01 March 2013
Group Buying Commitment and Sellers’
Competitive Advantages
YUXIN CHEN
Kellogg School of Management
Northwestern University
2001 Sheridan Rd.
Evanston, IL 60208
yuxin-chen@kellogg.northwestern.edu
XINXIN LI
School of Business
University of Connecticut
2100 Hillside Rd.
Storrs, CT 06269
xli@business.uconn.edu
This paper examines a model of duopoly firms selling to an exogenously formed buyer group
consisting of members with heterogeneous preferences. Two research questions are addressed: (1)
when is it optimal for a buyer group to commit to exclusive purchase from a single seller,and (2)
how does the presence of group buying and the exclusive purchase commitment associated with
it affect firms’ incentives to invest in quality improvement? We find that, even though exclusive
purchase commitment benefits buyers when the competing products provide similar quality,
it may lower buyer surplus if one product is significantly advantaged and/or the competing
products are not highly differentiated horizontally. This result is robust even if the buyer group
is formed endogenously. In addition, contingent on the similarity between the competing sellers’
investment costs, the sellers’ incentives to improve quality may be positively or negatively affected
by the presence of group buying.
1. Introduction
Buyers may purchase as groups in order to obtain favorable deals from sellers. For
example, employees in large companies and organizations usually purchase various
products and services as groups through their employers.1Group buying not only has
important implications to suppliers, procuring companies, and group members, but also
plays an important role in the whole economy. In 2007, over 177 million people purchased
health insurance as groups through their employers (DeNavas-Waltet al., 2008). In 2009,
92 million workers in the United States saved through employer-managed retirement
plans (SPARK, 2009).2A large number of buyer alliances also exist in various industries
The authors are listed alphabetically and contributed equally to the paper.The authors thank the coeditor and
two anonymous reviewers for valuable comments and suggestions. Yuxin Chen is currently visiting China
Europe International Business School as a Zhongkun Group VisitingChair Professor of Marketing.
1. Examples include health insurance packages (Enthoven, 1993), retirement plans (Dulebohn, 2002), IT
hardware (Greenstein, 1993), software(Hunt and Westfall, 2003), telecommunication equipment (Bruno-Britz,
2008), airline tickets, and hotels.
2. “The Case for Employer-Sponsored Retirement Plans—Coverage, Participation and Retirement Secu-
rity,”The SPARK Institute, Inc., May 2009.
C
2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Volume22, Number 1, Spring 2013, 164–183
Group Buying and Competitive Advantage 165
and across different countries for the purpose of negotiating lower prices from suppliers
(Chae and Heidhues, 2004).
A critical decision for a buyer group facing competing sellers to make is whether
to commit to exclusive purchase from a single seller, as the power of a buyer group
not only comes from its size but also from its ability to make such an commitment
(Dana, 2012). Committing to exclusive purchase consolidates demand and may intensify
seller competition. On the other hand, purchasing exclusively from a single seller
may compromise buyers’ heterogeneous preferences. In reality, exclusive purchase
commitment is observed in some cases but not in others (Maxwell and Temin, 2002).
Large employers usually use one of the two procurement models (Galvin and Delbanco,
2005): the “industrial purchasing approach” in which they contract with a single seller
to provide products or services, or the “managed competition model” in which options
from multiple suppliers are presented to employees from which each employee makes
their own choices. Thus, an important question is when it is optimal for a buyer group
to commit to exclusive purchase.
To examine this research question, we develop and analyze a stylized model
with two asymmetric sellers competing for a group of heterogeneous buyers. We find
that exclusive purchase commitment is optimal only if neither seller has a significant
competitive advantage, that is, sellers are not too asymmetric in quality. This result
arises because the advantage of exclusive purchase commitment in inducing more
price competition among sellers diminishes when the asymmetry in sellers’ competitive
advantages grows. We also find that exclusive purchase commitment is more likely
to be optimal if sellers’ products are more horizontally differentiated. The reason is
that buyers, when purchasing individually, have to pay higher prices when sellers are
more horizontally differentiated. In this situation, the buyer group’s incentive to induce
additional price competition among sellers through exclusive purchase commitment
dominates the potential loss it suffers, as some members have to consume the less-
preferred product. We find these results to be robust when we extend our model to
allow the buyer group to form endogenously.
Wethen extend our basic model to incorporate sellers’ quality investment decisions
to examine: how will group buying affect sellers’ investments in quality improvement?
Weshow that with symmetric costs of quality improvement, sellers invest more in quality
improvement when buyers purchase as a group. Interestingly, the opposite result may
occur in the asymmetric case—with asymmetric costs of quality improvement, sellers
may invest less in quality improvement when buyers purchase as a group. The intuition
is that a weak competitor (i.e., the seller with higher cost of quality investment) may
find it optimal to maintain a large quality gap with its rival in order to discourage the
buyer group from purchasing exclusively.
Our research is closely related to the literature on exclusive dealing and group
buying.3
Within the exclusive dealing literature, O’Brien and Shaffer (1997) examine how
nonlinear pricing affects the incentives for market foreclosure when two manufacturers
contract with a monopolist retailer. One of their results suggests that the retailer always
3. Besides the papers that we discuss in details below,related research includes Chae and Heidhues (2004),
Chen (2003), Chipty and Snyder (1999), Dobson and Waterson (1997), Ellison and Snyder (2010), Horn and
Wolinsky (1988), Inderst (2007), Snyder (1996), (1998), Stole and Zwiebel (1996), and von Ungern-Sternberg
(1996). Although these studies focus on buyer size as the source of bargaining power, we examine how
committing to exclusive purchase may benefit a buyer group regardless of its size. There is also an emerging
literature on online group buying (Kauffmanand Wang, 2002; Anand and Aron, 2003; Jing and Xie, 2011). This
literature primarily examines sellers’ strategies but we focus on buyers’ decisions on group buying.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT