Globalization, Ownership Structures and Productivity Dispersion

Date01 February 2014
AuthorJin‐tae Hwang,Sung‐min Kim
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12075
Published date01 February 2014
Globalization, Ownership Structures and
Productivity Dispersion
Sung-min Kim and Jin-tae Hwang*
Abstract
We investigate the heterogeneous effects of productivity dispersion on firms’ organizational choices,
depending upon sectoral characteristics. Using trade data on imports from non-related parties (outsourc-
ing) and related parties (integration) in the South, we show that productivity dispersion would increase
imports from the South with outsourcing in the low headquarter intensity sector, along with an increasing
fraction of the intra-firm imports in the high headquarter intensity sector, which is consistent with the pre-
dictions from the theory. Considering the bounded nature of a share of the intra-firm imports, a quasi-
maximum likelihood estimation was used.
1. Introduction
In The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith describes the division of labor with an
example of the production process in a pin factory. Focusing on only a narrow range
of tasks, each worker can perform his job efficiently and achieve improvements in
productivity and dexterity fully. In the late eighteenth-century England, however,
transportation for intermediate inputs and communication for delivering instructions
over long distances were very slow and costly. As a consequence, geographic concen-
tration is the most important factor, a sine qua non, in production by specialization,
and only completely finished goods are exchanged and traded by producers to con-
sumers (Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg, 2012).
In the following two centuries, these trends of agglomeration in the production and
trade of finished products were continued. Recent technological changes and trade
liberalization, however, have eliminated the limitations on division of labor by reduc-
ing transaction and communication costs, and thereby the growth of productivity by
specialization and production fragmentations became possible with an expansion in
market size. That is, as the transportation of partially produced goods and intermedi-
ate goods grew much faster and communications, much easier than before, the previ-
ous concentrated production in one place are now spread out to make full use of
factor costs and expertise differences across places. Therefore, the international disin-
tegration of production process and specialization across borders has become the
current main features of the international economy.
Much has been written about these rising trends in international production
fragmentation (Feenstra and Hanson, 1996; Feenstra, 1998; Antras and Helpman,
2004; Batra and Beladi, 2010; Goswami, 2011; Beladi et al., 2011; Grossman and
Rossi-Hansberg, 2012). The Boeing 787 Dreamliner, as introduced in Grossman
and Rossi-Hansberg (2012), is a good example. The 787 Dreamliner is produced by 50
* Hwang: Department of Financial Policy, Korea Insurance Research Institute, 35-4, Yoido-dong,
Youngdeungpo-gu, Seoul 150-600, Korea. Tel: +82-2-3775-9024; Fax: +82-2-3775-9104; E-mail: jt0813
@kiri.or.kr or jt0813@gmail.com. Kim:Korea University, 145, Anam-ro, Seongbuk-gu, Seoul 136-701, Korea.
Review of Development Economics, 18(1), 152–161, 2014
DOI:10.1111/rode.12075
© 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT