Global public goods and unilateral matching mechanisms

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12300
AuthorWeifeng Liu,Wolfgang Buchholz
Published date01 April 2020
Date01 April 2020
Received: 21 March2017 Accepted: 26 February2018
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12300
ARTICLE
Global public goods and unilateral matching
mechanisms
Wolfgang Buchholz1Weifeng Liu2
1Universityof Regensburg and CESifo Munich
2CrawfordSchool of Public Policy, The Australian
NationalUniversity
WolfgangBuchholz, Department of Economics,
Universityof Regensburg, 93040 Regensburg,
Germany(wolfgang.buchholz@ur.de).
WeifengLiu, Crawford Building 132, Lennox
Crossing,Canberra, ACT,2601, Australia
(dr.weifeng.liu@gmail.com).
While conventional agreements on international public goods
require bilateral or multilateralcooperation, we show that unilateral
actionthrough matching mechanismswith a self-commitmentdevice
can possibly generate Pareto-improving outcomes. Even without
commitment, unilateral matching may also benefit both players at
corner situations. We further characterize the conditions under
which this desirable outcome is achieved, particularly highlighting
the role of the income distribution and its interplay with the pref-
erences. Moreover,we propose a variant of unilateral matching that
can generate Pareto-improving outcomes regardless of the prefer-
ences and the income distribution, indicating that income inequality
may not be an obstacle for improving public good provision through
unilateral matching.
1INTRODUCTION
It is well known that public goods are generally underprovided when provision depends on agents'voluntary contri-
butions (see Cornes & Sandler, 1996). At the national level, conventional centralized approaches such as Pigouvian
taxes and subsidies can be used to cure this underprovision through government intervention. However, in the case
of global public goods, there is no supranational government so that international cooperation is required to improve
public good provision.In general, such international agreements require bilateral or multilateral cooperation, but inter-
national cooperation proves very difficult in practice. The most relevant exampleis climate negotiations, which have
gained much attention but whose effect has been rather limited so far. In this context, a large literaturehas investi-
gated international agreements from a game-theoretic perspective showing the difficulties of attaining a stable and
effective agreement (see, e.g., Barrett, 2003, 2007; Finus, 2001; Sandler,1997, 2004).
Against this background, this paper aims at exploring unilateral solutions that can improve global public good pro-
vision and generate Pareto-improvingoutcomes when one player takes actions as a leader while the other player plays
a Nash game as a follower.If the outcome is profitable for both players, then the leader has strong incentives to imple-
ment the actions and, more importantly,does not require cooperation by the other player.Very rare literature explores
such unilateral mechanisms to improve public good provisionas, for example, Buchholz, Cornes, Peters, and Rübbelke
(2015) who examine a unilateral matching approach in a two-player model of a public good economy. This approach
envisages one player subsidizing public good contributions of the other player through matching, thus reducing the
effective public good price of the recipient. More specifically, at the first stage, one player announces a matching
Journal of Public Economic Theory.2018;1–17. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet c
2018 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. 1
338 © 2018 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:338–354.
2ANDLIU
rate indicating by how much the player would subsidize public good contributions of the other player; at the second
stage, both players decide independently their flat contributions to the public good while the player who announces
the matching rate at the first stage also provides matching contributions. For example,should one player announce a
matching rate of 0.1 at the first stage, she would provide 0.1 units of the public good as a matching contribution if the
other player providesone unit of the public good at the second stage. 1
Under such a unilateral matching mechanism it has been shown that the matching player is better off while the
matched player is worse off (see Bergstrom, 1989; Roberts, 1987). Toachieve a Pareto improvement, the matching
player therefore must apply an ancillary instrument besides unilateral matching. Buchholz et al. (2015) show that a
commitment device can serve as such an instrument. More specifically, theyestablish that at an interior equilibrium
where both players make positive public good contributions, the matching equilibrium would be Pareto improvingif
the matching player commits not to reduce her flat contribution to the public good below her initial level and at the
same time if the private and the public good are substitutes for the matched player.
In general, given such two instruments—a matching mechanism and a commitment device—the leader's unilateral
action can potentially achieve Pareto-improvingoutcomes, but there may be infinite pairs of matching rates and com-
mitment levelsfor attaining such outcomes. In this paper,we restrict our attention to the case in which the leader com-
mits her flat contribution to the public good at her level in the initial Nash equilibrium and proposes a small matching
rate. Our motivation of focusing on this case is twofold. First, the Nash equilibrium as the outcome of noncooperative
public good provision is normally considered to be the starting point from which policies or mechanisms are designed
to bring public good supply closer to the efficient level. Second, focusing our analysis on small matching ratesis related
tothe literature on tax policy design. From the perspective of informational requirement, it is much easier to implement
small Pareto-improvingtax reforms than to attain overall optimal tax policy because the former requires only informa-
tion of the current position while the latter requires information of a large range of positions (see, e.g., Deaton, 1987;
Myles, 1995). In practice, the information required for small tax reforms is often directly observable or can be inferred
from the current position, but the information of entire preferences, demands, and production possibilities needed
for optimal taxation is simply not obtainable. This information problem obviously becomes even more severe at the
international level because it is much more difficult to obtain aggregate information for countries with heterogeneous
agents.
In the same spirit as Pareto-improving tax reforms, in this paper we are interested in Pareto-improving outcomes
in the context of unilateral matching, and thus consider a marginal matching rate and a commitment with regard to
the initial position, which is observable and thus servesas a convenient focal point for both players. Given this marginal
variation,we systematically examine sufficient conditions of achieving Pareto improvements under unilateral matching
with commitment, and extendthe analysis of Buchholz et al. (2015) in several aspects, particularly highlighting the role
of the income distribution and its interplay with the preferences.
More specifically, first we show that the possibility for Paretoimprovements not only depends on the preferences
of the recipient but also on the income distribution between the two players. At an interior equilibrium, if the match-
ing player commits to her initial public good contribution and announces a marginal matching rate,a Pareto-improving
equilibrium occurs in either of the two cases: (1) the private and the public good are substitutes for the matched player;
(2) the private and the public good are complements for the matched player and the income of the recipient is suffi-
ciently large compared to the matching player.
Second, we examine unilateral matching schemes at corner equilibria, in which the income inequality is large so
that one player does not provide public good contributions at the initial equilibrium (see Bergstrom, Blume, & Varian,
1986). Such corner equilibria are important not only in theory,but also in reality due to large income inequality in the
current world, which has constantly been a major concern in international climate negotiations. There are two cases
of unilateral matching at the corner.One is that the contributing player matches the noncontributing player while the
1Matching mechanisms were first suggested by Guttman (1978, 1987) and have been refined and applied in various waysbut all in bilateral or multilateral
contexts.See, for example, Boadway, Pestieau, and Wildasin (1989), Danziger and Schnytzer(1991), Althammer and Buchholz (1993), Varian (1994a, 1994b),
Falkinger(1996), Boadway, Song, and Tremblay(2007, 2011), Buchholz, Cornes, and Rübbelke (2011, 2012, 2014), and Liu (2018).
BUCHHOLZ ANDLIU 3
339

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT