Global public goods and coalition formation under matching mechanisms

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12294
Date01 June 2018
Published date01 June 2018
Received: 16 October 2017 Accepted: 21 February2018
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12294
ARTICLE
Global public goods and coalition formation under
matching mechanisms
Weifeng L iu
TheAustralian National University
WeifengLiu, Crawford School of Public Policy,
TheAustralian National University, Crawford
Building132, Lennox Crossing, Canberra, ACT,
2601,Australia (dr.weifeng.liu@gmail.com).
This paper links coalition theory with matching mechanisms in the
presence of global public goods among heterogeneous players. This
matching coalition may achieve Pareto-improving outcomes while
avoiding side payments. The paper characterizesconditions of coali-
tion profitability and stability at both interior and corner equilibria.
It is generally much harder to satisfy stability conditions than prof-
itability conditions. A matching coalition is more profitable but less
stablewith a larger matching rate. Empirically there is no stable coali-
tionbut this can be overcome by introducing reputation mechanisms.
There always existsa stable grand matching coalition if players value
their reputation. The matching coalition faces a trade-off between
matching depth and breadth.
1INTRODUCTION
As the world is increasingly moving toward economic globalization and integration, more and more transboundary
externalities emerge such as transnational pollution, international trade,financial crises, development aid, and conta-
gious diseases (Sandler, 2004). In the presence of such global public goods, international cooperation is required to
reach optimal outcomes, but this proves difficult in practice due to the absence of a supranational government with
enforcement power. The most relevant example is climate negotiations, which havegained much attention but little
progress. To overcomeunderprovision of such global public goods, a large literature examines cooperative games in
coalitional form (see, e.g., Barrett, 1994; Carraro & Siniscalco, 1993; Finus, Altamirano-Cabrera, &Van Ierland, 2005;
Hoel & Schneider, 1997).1A typical coalitional game is often comprised of four stages: (1) players decide whether to
sign an agreement or to behaveas singletons; (2) signatories decide on the public good provision cooperativelyso as to
maximize the aggregate welfare of the coalition when taking the reaction of the nonsignatories into account; (3) given
the public good provision of signatories, each nonsignatory chooses his or her public good provision so as to maximize
his or her own welfare; (4) signatories decide how the welfare gain is distributed.
There are two major issues of this coalitional game in practice particularly at the international level. First, even if
players decide to form a coalition, it is difficult to maximize the aggregate welfare of the coalition because of diver-
gent interests and incomplete information. At the international level, divergent interests involvemultiple dimensions
1Pelegand Sudholter (2003) provide a comprehensive coverage of cooperative games; Ray (2007) presents a general theory of coalition formation that com-
binescooperative and noncooperative approaches.
Journal of Public Economic Theory.2018;20:325–355. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet c
2018 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. 325
326 LIU
including economic benefits, political relationships, and cultural background, and incomplete information includes
numerous uncertainties as to national incomes, aggregate preferences, and costs and benefits of public goods. One
solution to mitigate this issue is to form a coalition among subgroups of like-mindedplayers (see, e.g., Buchholz, Cornes,
& Rübbelke, 2014; Buchholz, Haslbeck, & Sandler, 1998). Countries with common culture, similar income levelsand
national preferences are more likelyto make ambitious agreements. However, one of the most challenging problems in
climatenegotiations is the conflict between developing and developed countries, and these two groups diverge in many
dimensions including historical responsibility,mitigation capability, and current welfare. Therefore, the first issue can-
not be solved by forming a coalition among like-minded countries. Instead, more realistically,countries should form a
coalition to achievea less ambitious solution—a Pareto-improving outcome, that is, each coalition member is better off
than without a coalition, rather than maximizing the aggregate welfare in a coalition.
The second issue involves side payments.In the conventional coalitional game, players have to decide how to share
costs or distribute gains among the coalition. This is also very difficult without a central government because players
often have subjective perceptions of equity in sharing costs or distributing gains and also because playersare subject
to political constraintsof international transfers. For example, developed and developing countries haveagreed to pro-
tect climate on the basis of equity as early as the 1990s when the United Nations Framework Conventionon Climate
Change was established, but it is difficult to reach a consensus on equity in practice given their different responsibil-
ity, capability,preferences, costs and benefits, and so forth. In addition, Summers (2007) argues that, due to political
constraints, governments are unlikely to write substantial checks to each other pursuant to international treaties in
climate change. Therefore, it would be pragmatically useful to apply a mechanism that can avoidside payments among
players.
This paper considers a coalitional setting under matching mechanisms and focuses on Pareto-improving outcomes
while avoiding side payments. The matching mechanisms, first suggested by Guttman (1978, 1987), work as a two-
stage game. At the first stage, each player announces a matching rate indicating by how much the player would sub-
sidize public good contributions of all other players; at the second stage, all players decide independently their flat
contributions to the public good while the players announcing matching rates at the first stage also provide matching
contributions to other players. For example,should one announce a matching rate of 0.1 at the first stage, the player
would provide 0.1 units of the public good as a matching contribution if another player providesone unit of the public
good at the second stage. The idea of this mechanism is still to stick to the noncooperative mode of public good pro-
vision but meanwhile to subsidize individual public good contributions and hence to lower the effective price of the
public good. Guttman (1978) shows that with quasi-linear preferences, the subgame perfect equilibrium in such a two-
stage game of two identical players is fully efficient. Danziger and Schnytzer (1991) generalize this result to multiple
agents with more general preferences. More broadly,Moore and Repullo (1988) show that subgame perfect equilibria
ofsuch multistage g amescan implement efficient allocations. However, these multistage games are far from implemen-
tationdue to their sophisticated structures. As Moore and Repullo also point out, “the mechanisms we c onstruct to deal
with a general environment are far from simple: agents move simultaneously at each stage and their strategysets are
unconvincingly rich. We present such mechanisms to demonstrate what is possible, not what is realistic.” Therefore,
this paper considers a realistic application of this matching approach into coalition formation. As an earlier study in
this direction, Buchholz et al. (2014) examine coalition formation under matching mechanisms among homogeneous
players.More specifically, they assume that all players are completely homogeneous in the preference and the income,
and consider a two-stage game: Coalition members cooperatively determine the matching rate at the first stage, and
then play a noncooperative game against coalition outsiders at the second stage. This model of homogeneous players
is a very special case with symmetric results across players.
This paper relaxes the assumption of homogeneity by allowing players to havedifferent income levels. This relax-
ation is clearly important given the large income heterogeneity across countries in the current world, but gives rise to
severaltheoretical issues. First, as the outcomes are asymmetric across players, not only the coalition size but also the
member identity matters for coalition formation. Second, given the income heterogeneity,it is a key issue to make poor
players better off in a matching coalition without resorting to side payments. Third, there are potentially corner equi-
libria in which a subgroup of either coalition insiders or outsiders provide no public good contributions. Fourth, there

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT