Global Finance, Labor Politics, and the Political Economy of Housing Prices

Published date01 September 2017
DOI10.1177/0032329217702102
AuthorAidan Regan,Alison Johnston
Date01 September 2017
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329217702102
Politics & Society
2017, Vol. 45(3) 327 –358
© 2017 SAGE Publications
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0032329217702102
journals.sagepub.com/home/pas
Article
Global Finance, Labor
Politics, and the Political
Economy of Housing Prices
Alison Johnston
Oregon State University
Aidan Regan
University College Dublin
Abstract
International political economy identifies declining nominal interest rates, securitization,
and financial liberalization as drivers of rising housing prices. Despite witnessing these
common credit shocks, however, developed economies experienced divergent
trends in housing inflation since the 1980s. We offer a comparative political economy
explanation of variation in house prices, arguing that by restraining household incomes,
wage-setting institutions can blunt financial liberalization’s inflationary impact on housing
markets. Employing quantitative analysis and a comparative study of Ireland and the
Netherlands, we uncover two findings. First, countries where political coalitions in
the export sector held veto powers over those in the nontraded sector in national
wage setting realized lower housing inflation. Second, the impact of sectoral coalitions
on housing prices in OECD countries is similar to that of financial variables. Our
results suggest that the organization of labor politics continues to play an important
role in mitigating the destabilizing effects of global finance on developed economies.
Keywords
housing prices, labor politics, growth models, international political economy,
comparative political economy
Corresponding Author:
Alison Johnston, Department of Political Science, School of Public Policy, Oregon State University,
339 Bexell Hall, Corvallis, OR 97333, USA.
Email: Alison.Johnston@oregonstate.edu
702102PASXXX10.1177/0032329217702102Politics & SocietyJohnston and Regan
research-article2017
328 Politics & Society 45(3)
The US subprime mortgage crisis and subsequent 2008 global financial crisis demon-
strated the devastating effects of rapid housing inflation (and housing bubbles) on
national economies. In addition to their destabilizing economic effects,1 housing bub-
bles also have important political implications. Sudden declines in housing prices can
be deeply regressive if disproportionate shares of poor households store their wealth
in (subprime) mortgages.2 Likewise, Ansell3 has shown that rising or falling housing
prices impact individuals’ electoral preferences toward the welfare state.
International political economy (IPE) highlights a number of factors that led to
asset bubbles within OECD countries in the late 2000s: declines in nominal interest
rates, financial liberalization, the proliferation of cross-border capital flows, and
(mortgage) securitization.4 These developments also had important implications for
real estate, as they reduced the costs of (mortgage) borrowing for households and
increased the volume of debt instruments that banks could extend to households.
However, IPE accounts of global financial and credit market trends, which tend to
rely heavily on the US’s experience,5 fall short in explaining the variation in housing
prices within the OECD. Financial liberalization and reductions in nominal interest
rates impacted all developed economies since the 1970s. Despite this common credit
shock, there was a wide divergence in housing inflation across countries. Some
(Ireland and Spain) witnessed rapidly rising prices in the 1990s and the 2000s, while
others (Germany and Japan) witnessed average declines.6
We offer a novel political argument to explain variation in house prices across
developed economies. Shifting toward a comparative political economy (CPE) per-
spective, we suggest that the labor politics that govern income growth are a crucial
determinant of housing inflation. Our approach complements the recent call by
Baccaro and Pontusson7 to rethink the supply-side bias of CPE by bringing the politi-
cal determinants of aggregate demand back in. While (international) credit shocks are
important for the emergence of rapid housing inflation, we highlight that buoyant
housing price growth also requires the presence of income shocks, which are shaped
by domestic wage setting and labor politics.
We argue and empirically demonstrate that countries with labor market institutions
that allotted the export sector8 agenda-setting or veto powers in national wage setting
(what we call “export-led political coalitions”) over the nontraded sector (what we call
“domestic-led political coalitions”) realized moderated income growth, which miti-
gated households’ demand for mortgages and, in turn, housing inflation. In other
words, countries with labor market institutions coordinated by political coalitions in
the export sectors of the economy enabled a countercyclical incomes policy that tamed
the inflationary effects of cheap credit on housing markets.
Our analysis of the political determinants underlying housing prices makes three
important contributions to political science. First, it illustrates that labor politics con-
tinue to play an important role in mitigating the destabilizing effects of global financial
liberalization on developed economies. Second, our results suggest that the old corpo-
ratist debate on the relationship between wage setting and macroeconomic outcomes
is not dead, but has manifested itself in new ways with important implications for
(housing-driven) wealth inequality.9 Third, it reverses the causal arrow in current
political science literature that dissects the effects of housing prices on politics (namely,
Johnston and Regan 329
on individuals’ political preferences for the welfare state10), by detailing how politics
affect housing prices.
IPE and CPE Explanations of Housing Inflation: A Credit
Supply-Side Bias?
IPE literature identifies a link between financial liberalization and the loosening of
capital controls, and the presence of asset bubbles.11 Increased international capital
flows, and new “innovative” financial products, such as (mortgage-backed) securities
(MBSs), gave governments and households a greater capacity to borrow due to higher
credit volume. Moreover, the harmonization of financial market rules among devel-
oped countries reduced regulatory uncertainty among foreign lenders, providing fur-
ther incentives for lenders to increase credit supply.12
Increased capital mobility in developed economies also aligned with reductions in
nominal interest rates, which made credit cheaper. Since the late 1970s, the removal
of capital controls and reduced exchange rate volatility that accompanied the transition
to a low inflation regime produced lower nominal interest rates. These developments
were magnified in Western Europe for countries that participated in the European
Monetary System (EMS) and joined the EU’s Economic and Monetary Union in 1999.
Under the EMS, various Western European countries committed themselves to a fixed
exchange rate regime, which prompted them to initiate difficult wage and price adjust-
ments in order achieve exchange rate convergence.13 These adjustments (and the
removal of capital controls) reduced exchange rate risk, while the Euro eliminated it
completely, enabling lower nominal interest rates in EMU countries that previously
had high borrowing costs (notably Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain). Abundant credit
and declining borrowing costs established an environment conducive toward increased
private and public borrowing, which, through cross-national capital flows, became
intimately connected to securitization originating in the United States.14
The IPE literature alerts us to a constellation of factors that would fuel housing
inflation from the 1980s onward. Cheaper and more abundant credit, coupled with
MBSs’ reduction of default risk exposure, allowed banks to increase mortgage supply.
Households thus had greater capacity to borrow, allowing them to buy larger mort-
gages and accumulate greater personal debt. Yet, despite its important effects on hous-
ing markets, international financial liberalization fails fully to account for the wide
cross-national variation in housing prices among developed countries. Financial liber-
alization and reductions in nominal interest rates impacted all advanced economies in
the 1980s, 1990s, and 2000s. And although there was heterogeneity in the speed of
financial liberalization (countries that liberalized capital markets earlier witnessed
smaller nominal interest rates declines during the 1980s and 1990s than those that
liberalized later), heterogeneity in interest rate declines does not fully explain the
divergence in housing price growth across the OECD.
Figure 1 presents bivariate comparisons of changes in nominal/real interest rates,
and nominal/real housing inflation, between 1990 and 2007 for seventeen OECD coun-
tries15 (we select 2007 as the end date, because the 2008 global financial crisis marked
a sharp break in previous trends). Reductions in nominal interest rates fail to correspond

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT