FX Intervention in the New Keynesian Model

AuthorZINEDDINE ALLA,RAPHAEL A. ESPINOZA,ATISH R. GHOSH
Date01 October 2020
Published date01 October 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12683
DOI: 10.1111/jmcb.12683
ZINEDDINE ALLA
RAPHAEL A. ESPINOZA
ATISH R. GHOSH
FX Intervention in the New Keynesian Model
Wedevelop an open-economy New Keynesian Model with foreign exchange
(FX) intervention in the presence of a financial accelerator and shocks to risk
appetite in international capital markets. We obtain closed-form solutions
for optimal monetary and FX intervention policies assuming the central
bank cannot commit to future policies, and we compare the solution to that
under policy commitment. We show howFX intervention can help reduce
the volatility of the exchange rate, of inflation, and of the output gap, thus
mitigating welfare losses associated with shocks in the international capital
markets. We also show that, when the financial accelerator is strong, there
is a risk of indeterminacy (self-fulfilling currency and inflation movements)
although FX intervention can reduce this risk and thus reinforce the cred-
ibility of the inflation targeting regime. Model simulations match well the
impact of a VIX shock obtained by local projections on a panel of inflation
targeting emerging markets.
JEL codes: E52, E58, F31
Keywords: central bank reserves, capital flows, equilibrium determinacy,
open-economy New Keynesian Model, portfolio balance model,
speculative attack.
DESPITE THE MOVE TOWARD GREATER exchange rate flexibility
over the past 30 years, many central banks—including some with inflation targeting
frameworks—seem to havetwin objectives of price stability and (at least some degree
We are grateful for the comments and suggestions from Suman Basu, Olivier Blanchard, Paolo Cav-
allino, Nicolas Coeurdacier, Emmanuel Farhi, Federico Grinberg, Philippe Martin, Helene Rey, Lars
Svensson, Pablo Winant, Felipe Zanna, and from two anonymousreferees as well as seminar participants
at the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and at the Bank of England. The views expressed in this paper
are solely those of the authors and do not represent those of the IMF or IMF policy.
ZINEDDINE ALLA is at Sciences Po,Paris (E-mail: zineddine.alla@gmail.com). RAPHAEL A. ESPINOZA is a
Deputy Division Chief at the International Monetary Fund (E-mail: respinoza@imf.org). ATISHR. GHOSH
is a Deputy Director at the International Monetary Fund (E-mail: aghosh@imf.org).
Received March 27, 2018; and accepted in revised form June 4, 2019.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 52, No. 7 (October 2020)
C
2019 The Ohio State University
The International Monetary Fund retains copyright and all other rights in the manuscript of
this article as submitted for publication.
1756 :MONEY,CREDIT AND BANKING
of) exchange rate stability.1The principal instruments at their disposal are the policy
interest rate and sterilized intervention in the foreign exchange (FX) market.2But
in the canonical New Keynesian Model (e.g., Gali and Monacelli 2005), the policy
interest rate suffices for stability because the two objectives of stable inflation and
a zero output gap coincide (the “divine coincidence”): there is no exchange rate
objective, and therefore no need for FX intervention. Our purpose in this paper is
to examine whether shocks (e.g., “risk-on/risk-off” episodes) in international capital
markets can give rise to a rationale for sterilized intervention, and to analyze how FX
intervention affects the credibility of an inflation targeting regime.
Our framework, building on the canonical New Keynesian Model, incorporates
three key features. First, the existence of shocks in international capital markets that
result in variations in the cost of capital to the economy. Second, financial frictions
in international capital markets that break uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), and
render sterilized intervention effective through a portfolio balance channel. Third, a
working capital requirement for firms’ production that amplifies the effects of the
capital market shocks on the real economy.3
The issues we examine are of salience to both emerging market and advanced
economies. As is well known, many emerging market central banks exhibit a “fear of
floating” (Calvo and Reinhart 2002), and will often respond to capital inflow surges
and sudden stops using monetary policy and FX intervention (see also Fratzscher
et al. 2019). Switzerland provides an advanced economy example of the use of
FX intervention. As the Euro crisis deepened in 2011, leading to large financial
flows into Switzerland, the Swiss National Bank (SNB) announced a ceiling for
the franc, backing it with aggressive intervention. Despite some initial success in
mitigating capital inflows and stabilizing the exchange rate, there were concerns that
the market might be anticipating a revaluation,and that such expectations would result
in a self-fulfilling strengthening of the currency as the ballooning reserves became
unsustainably costly to hold (in effect, a “reverse” speculative attack). Recognizing
that one policy instrument may not suffice to contain speculative flows, the SNB cut
its policy rate from 0.25% to 0.75% in January 2015.
The framework we develop is well suited to analyzing optimal policy in the face
of shocks in international capital markets, which are particularly important for small
open economies. As Itskhoki and Mukhin (2017) show, moreover, they are also
crucial to understanding the major exchange rate puzzles documented in the inter-
national finance literature. We begin by showing that these shocks break the divine
coincidence and make sterilized intervention a valuable addition to the central bank’s
1. According to the IMF classification, around one-third of all countries either de jure or de facto
manage their exchange rate.
2. Sterilized intervention consists of the central bank purchasing or selling foreign currency-
denominated assets with corresponding sales or purchases of domestic currency assets in order to leave
the money supply unchanged. If FX intervention is not sterilized, then it does not constitute a separate
instrument from monetary policy.
3. See Farhi and Werning (2014) or Woodford (2012) for models in which financial frictions justify
the use of capital controls or unconventional policies. In practice, FX intervention is the most commonly
used tool after the policy interest rate.
ZINEDDINE ALLA, RAPHAEL A. ESPINOZA, AND ATISHR. GHOSH :1757
policy toolkit. We then show that under discretionary policies, the availability of FX
intervention helps reduce the “stabilization bias” associated with the central bank’s
lack of commitment (Clarida, Gali, and Gertler 1999), where the benefit depends on
the degree of openness of the economy. Finally, we show how the availability of FX
intervention as policy instrument can also reduce the zone of equilibrium indetermi-
nacy (which we interpret as the zone where speculative attacks are possible) thereby
contributing to macro-economic stability and to the credibility of inflation targeting.
The paper thus contributes to the literature on the desirability of FX intervention for
inflation-targeting central banks, in which Ghosh, Ostry, and Chamon (2016), and
Blanchard et al. (2016) are recent examples.
Beyond developing a tractable model of FX intervention in a New Keynesian
Model, where sterilized intervention works through a portfolio balance channel, our
contribution is threefold. First, we derive closed-form solutions for the optimal policy
of the central bank under discretion and we compare our results to those obtained
under commitment, allowing us to analyze the costs of the lack of credibility. Our
results show that FX intervention can “lean against the wind” and can help offset
changes in investors’ risk appetite. However, since FX intervention carries welfare
costs (because it affects the international asset position of the economy), the central
bank only partially offsets these shocks. We also show that the welfare benefits of
using FX intervention after a 5% risk premium shock, (which would depreciate the
exchange rate by 10%) are sizeable, at around 0.4% of permanent consumption for
a standard calibration of the model. The comparison with the commitment solution
shows that a commitment technology would allow the central bank to achieve a
smaller deviation of inflation on impact and lower output volatility as inflation is
better anchored by the promise of stable future inflation. However, the welfare gains
from commitment are an order of magnitude smaller than the welfare gains obtained
from being able to use FX intervention on top of monetary policy.
Second, we show the importance of the financial accelerator for equilibrium in-
determinacy, and establish that FX intervention can be useful in limiting the risk of
self-fulfilling, “expectational,” bubbles in the exchange rate. In particular, we show
that a central bank that is more willing to use both FX intervention and conventional
interest rate policy is less likely to face the risk of indeterminacy.
Third, we establish the relevance of our model to emerging markets, as we show
that our simulations replicate well the macro-economic dynamics observed after
shocks to the VIX.
Our paper is related to the literature on third-generation speculative attacks and
sudden stops (Krugman 1999, Aghion, Bacchetta, and Banerjee 2000, Mendoza
2010). However, the New Keynesian modeling strategy we adopt makes our paper
closest to Farhi and Werning (2014), who show how capital controls are useful
instruments in economies hit by shocks to capital flows, and to Cavallino (2019),
who includes Gabaix and Maggiori (2015)’s microfoundation of FX intervention in
a New Keynesian Model solved under commitment.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 1 reviews the literature. Section 2
presents the open-economy model, in particular the mechanics of FX intervention,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT