From Drug Lords to Police State: The Effects of Order Transition on Local Economies

AuthorLeonardo Gentil-Fernandes,João V. Guedes-Neto,José Incio
Published date01 September 2022
Date01 September 2022
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00104140211060273
Subject MatterArticles
Article
Comparative Political Studies
2022, Vol. 55(10) 17651801
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00104140211060273
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
From Drug Lords to
Police State: The Effects
of Order Transition on
Local Economies
Leonardo Gentil-Fernandes
1
, João V. Guedes-Neto
1
and Jos´
e Incio
1
Abstract
What is the effect on local economies when the state intervenes to capture its
own territories back from non-state actors? In 2008, the government of Rio
de Janeiro, Brazil, implemented a policy to take control of favelas that were
previously dominated by organized crime groups (OCGs). We use day and
night luminosity to assess the effects of this program on economic growth.
The difference-in-differences design shows that state intervention has a
signif‌icant and negative average treatment effect on the favelas that received
the intervention. We further test a mechanism to explain this economic
downturn: institutional replacement. Based on crime data, we demonstrate
that this effect is caused by the destruction of local markets, especially illicit
activities. The data highlight the perils of order transition, even when OCGs
are removed by state actors. Furthermore, this paper reinforces the need for
policies that are mindful of the externalities of institutional shifts.
Keywords
politics of growth/development, democratization and regime change, Latin
American politics, political economy, organized crime
1
University of Pittsburgh, PA, USA
Author names are in alphabetical order.
Corresponding Author:
Leonardo Gentil-Fernandes, Department of Political Science, University of Pittsburgh, 230 South
Bouquet Street, Pittsburgh, PA 15213, USA.
Email: lef54@pitt.edu
By 2010, 22% of the population of Rio de Janeiro (Brazil) lived in favelas
(IBGE, 2010).
1
Many of them are controlled by organized crime and have no
access to state-operated public services. Their residents live under extreme
conditions, including open sewage and the constant risk of falling walls and
roofs. Previous governments have either overlooked this issue or adopted
unsuccessful programs that made the scene look like an unsolvable problem.
Poverty pockets concentrated in metropolitan areas are neither new nor
exclusive to Rio de Janeiro (Stokes, 1962; Davis, 2006). From Mumbai to
Chicago, criminal organizations have used poverty pockets in urban centers as
a source of recruitment, self-protection, and f‌inancial development
(Weinstein, 2008). In countries recovering from or passing through civil
conf‌licts (Asal et al., 2019; Kupatadze, 2012), criminal order replaces state
authority, offering a parallel source of stability to local communities (McGuire
& Olson, 1998). Far from anarchy, these organized crime groups (OCGs)
function as what Olson (1993) calls stationary banditry: They police, judge,
and tax as if they were the legitimate rulers of their communities. It is no
surprise that Tilly (1985) compared organized crime to state making.
What is the effect on local economies when the state intervenes to capture
their own territories back from these OCGs? This paper investigates the
economic impact of order transition in impoverished territories. We argue that
state intervention in areas previously controlled by groups that operate as
stationary bandits causes a temporary crisis, especially since order transition
leads to the partial destruction of local markets, thus decreasing income and
pushing economic activity down. At least until a new order has successfully
been established and managed to substitute the destroyed markets, such
transitions should lead to negative economic performance.
A recent policy implemented by the state government of Rio de Janeiro
provides an opportunity to test this theory. In 2008, it created the Unidades de
Pol´
ıcia Pacif‌icadora (Pacifying Police Units, hereafter UPPs) to handle the
expansion of organized crime in the citysfavelas as it prepared to host the
2016 Olympic Games and the 2014 World Cup (Ribeiro, 2014; Silva & Beato,
2013). UPPs represented a sudden and drastic increase of state presence in
locations where criminal order was the norm. We show that this order
transition caused a negative impact in the economy of favelas because of the
destruction of illicit markets.
This study offers at least three contributions to academics and practitioners.
The f‌irst of them is methodological. We study the effects of the im-
plementation of UPPs in the favelas of Rio de Janeiro based on a difference-in-
differences design. Utilizing measures from the Day/Night Band of Visible
Infrared Imaging Radiometer Suite (VIIRS-DNB), this paper relies on day and
night luminosity as a proxy for economic activity and growth (for a similar
approach, see Henderson et al., 2012). This is especially relevant given the
diff‌iculties of obtaining data from highly violent localities (Osorio, 2014) or
1766 Comparative Political Studies 55(10)
those where the informal sector tends to be predominant (Bickenbach et al.,
2016; DellAnno, 2007; Henderson et al., 2012). Implementing this mea-
surement to assess the impact of a policing initiative, we bring attentio n to the
availability and relevance of this tool for policy analysis. Our study shows a
negative impact in luminosity, evidencing a downturn in the economy of areas
that were already impoverished.
This f‌inding corroborates to the literature on criminal governance and the
economy of crime. Based on these streams of research, we already know that,
in pockets of state weakness(Lessing, 2020, p. 2), stationary banditry
2
facilitates local cooperation through the enforcement of selected contracts
(Olson, 1993; Koivu, 2016; McGuire & Olson, 1998). These OCGs have their
own bureaucratic procedures, disciplinary system, and even job benef‌its
beyond salary (Lessing & Willis, 2019). In competition against state order
(Barnes, 2017), they provide private security and build trust networks to
develop illicit markets (Albarrac´
ın, 2018; Koivu, 2016).
Indeed, these areas are not completely stateless, in that their residents still
vote and pay taxes, among other types of citizenship obligations (Lessing,
2020). In some cases, the state actors may even tolerate or associate with
criminal rule (Pansters, 2018; Snyder & Duran-Martinez, 2009). Yet, as we
show, the transition from this dual-domination to the states monopoly of force
disrupts illicit markets and institutions generating a partial reduction of in-
come in these localities. This f‌inding lends additional empirical evidence to
the thesis that criminal organizations develop their own markets, which are
unlikely to survive under state order.
Based on crime reports, we f‌ind support to the hypothesis that this eco-
nomic downturn is, indeed, led by the destruction of local shadow markets
during order transition. In brief, since part of the residents lost the income
previously generated by arms and drugs dealing, a spiral of demand shortage
affected other local markets, pushing economic activity down. These f‌indings
lead to our third contribution, which is directed at policymakers and other
practitioners. We raise awareness to the need for governments to be mindful of
the negative economic effects of order transition. As such, economic and
social policies that mitigate these negative impacts and facilitate the intro-
duction of new institutions should be implemented alongside state rule to
reduce the negative effects of order transition.
State and Non-State Order
The relevance of state order is well-established in the literature. Huntington
(1973, p. 1) introduces his seminal work by arguing that The United States,
Great Britain, and the Soviet Union have different forms of government, but in
all three systems the government governs.In his narrative, the same was not
true for the modernizing countries of Asia, Africa, and Latin America,
Gentil-Fernandes et al. 1767

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT