Free to escape? Economic freedoms, growth and poverty traps
Published date | 01 August 2022 |
Author | Donatella Saccone,Matteo Migheli |
Date | 01 August 2022 |
DOI | http://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12868 |
1518
|
Rev Dev Econ. 2022;26:1518–1554.
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Solow (1956) theorized the possibility that some poor countries would have fallen into a so- called
poverty trap. Their lower savings rates would indeed have led them to steady states characterized
by less capital and lower income per capita than those of affluent countries.1 Of course, coun-
tries should avoid poverty traps, which economists and policy- makers see as a highly undesirable
Received: 28 January 2021
|
Revised: 22 July 2021
|
Accepted: 11 January 2022
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12868
REGULAR ARTICLE
Free to escape? Economic freedoms, growth and
poverty traps
DonatellaSaccone1,2
|
MatteoMigheli2,3
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution- NonCommercial License, which permits use,
distribution and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited and is not used for commercial purposes.
© 2022 The Authors. Review of Development Economics published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
1University of Gastronomic Sciences, Bra
(CN), Italy
2OEET- Turin Centre on Emerging
Economies, Torino (TO), Italy
3Department of Economics and Statistics
“Cognetti de Martiis”, University of
Turin, Torino (TO), Italy
Correspondence
Matteo Migheli, Department of
Economics and Statistics “Cognetti de
Martiis”, University of Turin, Lungo Dora
Siena 100, I- 10153 Torino (TO), Italy.
Email: matteo.migheli@unito.it
Abstract
New evidence on the relationships between eco-
nomic freedoms and poverty traps is provided.
Methodologically, a new way to classify countries into
clusters is used, which stresses the relative position of
economies with respect to each other. The paper inves-
tigates whether economic freedoms have any impact on
shifts from one cluster to another, towards either better
or worse situations. Moreover, it analyzes the contribu-
tion of economic freedoms to avoid falling into a poverty
trap. The impacts of the five macro- components of the
index are studied separately. The results show that eco-
nomic freedoms help economies to grow and to avoid
poverty traps.
KEYWORDS
economic freedom, economic growth, poverty traps, transitions
JEL CLASSIFICATION
I32; O43; O47
|
1519
SACCONE and MIGHELI
outcome; consequently, many different economic policies have been designed and implemented
over time for countries to escape from or elude such traps (Kraay & McKenzie, 2014). Both na-
tional governments and international financial organizations such as the World Bank and the
International Monetary Fund have therefore pursued policies aimed at promoting economic
growth, especially in developing and (since the 1990s) transitioning countries.
Starting from the early 1980s, the so- called Washington Consensusinspired most of the policies
which, grounded in liberal and neoliberal theories, suggested liberalizing economies to render
them as close as possible to perfect market economies set on the best path to fast and sustainable
economic growth (Sachs etal.,2004). Implicitly, following this recipe would have minimized
the risk of falling into poverty traps. In the wake of such a policy orientation, some research and
policy- evaluation institutions developed indices to measure the degree of economic freedom of
a country, with the aim of assessing both the performance of economies in this respect and the
effects of the latter on economic growth. Although different indices measuring the level of eco-
nomic freedom of countries now exist, their representation of the phenomenon generally does
not vary significantly: Doucouliagos and Ulubasoglu (2006) prove that the effects of economic
freedom on economic growth do not vary with the index used. Eichengreen etal.(2013) show
that the existence of traps depends on the definition of categories (i.e. low- , middle- , and high-
income countries): the adoption of a relative rather than an absolute definition of thresholds
between these categories leads to different results and conclusions about the existence of and the
escape from poverty traps.
Starting from the latter conclusion, this paper contributes to the extant literature on the im-
pact of economic freedom on economic growth (measured as the growth of income per capita)
by adopting a new classification of economies, based on a measure that stresses relativity in the
positioning, to define poverty traps; and by applying such a relative classification to study how
economic freedom is associated to the transition of countries from one category to another and
focusing in particular on recessions and advancements. The reason for highlighting relativity is
that, while absolute thresholds either need continuous updates to keep reflecting the evolving
situation or risk of representing states that progressively lose adherence with reality, relative
measures update automatically, as they follow the same processes that govern the underlying
variables. In particular, this paper adopts the classification of economies proposed by Saccone
and Deaglio (2020), where countries are clustered into four groups: poor, emerging, booming,
and affluent. The methodology considers the relative position of countries with respect to both
the world average per- capita income and the world mean of its growth rate. The simultaneous
comparison of each country against these means allows us to evaluate them according to their
relative status (level of income per capita) and dynamics of per- capita income (growth rate); such
a strategy therefore combines the two variables that the literature has traditionally used sepa-
rately. The third section of the paper discusses this procedure in more detail.
The main aim of the paper is not to classify countries into the four categories individuated by
such a procedure nor to study the impact of economic freedom on the position of each country in
a cluster. In fact, Saccone and Deaglio (2020), who originally proposed the classification, already
presented an econometric analysis of the factors determining why a country belongs to one cat-
egory rather than to another at specific periods of time. However, they only marginally explored
the factors driving the transitions of countries across categories over time through a simple sta-
tistical analysis of frequencies and means for selected cases, also considering the role played by
economic freedom, and concluded by calling for a more sophisticated investigation of the tran-
sition patterns. The present paper answers such a call and, more specifically, aims to study how
economic freedom is associated with the transition of countries from one category to another by
1520
|
SACCONE and MIGHELI
focusing in particular on recessions and advancements. The purpose is to understand whether
economic freedom allows economies to avoid poverty and to follow virtuous growth paths, using
the aforementioned clustering strategy.
Following Carlsson and Lundström (2002) and Berggren (2003), the analysis presented in the
paper will consider not only an aggregate index of economic freedom (namely, that provided by
the Fraser Institute) but also its components. Indices of economic freedom, indeed, include sets
of indicators ranging from law enforcement to inflation stability: the literature (see Carlsson &
Lundström, 2002; Ott, 2018) clearly shows that different components of these indices have differ-
ent effects on economic growth, from negative to positive. The inclusion of the synthetic index
in empirical analysis is important, as it allows for assessing the overall weighed impact of all its
components. Therefore, on the one hand, the aggregate measure answers the question whether
economic freedom (generally speaking) enhances growth; on the other hand, its decomposition
allows us to understand which aspects are beneficial and which are not, allowing for precise pol-
icy recommendations. Given the composite nature of the indices of economic freedom, through-
out the paper the plural “economic freedoms” will be preferred to its singular form.
The results of the analysis set out in this paper show that economic freedom is in general a
positive ingredient for transitioning to higher clusters and allows poverty traps to be avoided.
However, some caveats are in order: on the one hand, when economies are characterized by high
levels ofincome inequality, they do not benefit from economic freedoms; on the other hand,
some components of the index seem to have a rather negative effect on countries with incomes
per capita below the world average, while the opposite holds for those above such a threshold. In
other words, economic freedoms should be implemented cautiously and policy- makers should
try to follow optimal sequencing of reforms.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section2 provides a general review of theoret-
ical and empirical studies on the relationships between growth, poverty traps, and economic
freedom. Section3 presents the methodology and data used in the empirical analysis. Section4
reports and discusses the main findings. Section5 concludes.
2
|
LITERATURE REVIEW
This section presents and critically discusses some of the most relevant works that assess the
existence of poverty traps, their causes and solutions. The second part of the section surveys the
works on measures of economic freedoms and their relationships with growth and poverty traps.
The literature on growth and development in economics has often inquired into the prob-
lem of so- called poverty traps (Nurske,1953; Azariadis & Stachurski, 2006), situations such that
poor countries are condemned to poverty by their own characteristics, which endogenously re-
create poverty.2 Solow (1956) and Swan (1956) are examples of theoretical models that predict
the existence of poverty traps for countries, whose savings rate is insufficient to allow capital
to accumulate enough to bring the country to an affluent steady state. Phillips and Sul (2009)
propose an econometric strategy that allows for clustering countries into five groups, according
to their per- capita income in 1970 and 2003. The authors show that the majority of countries
remained in the initial group (including that of poor economies) over the 34years considered;
nevertheless, a few countries were able to leave their club to transition to another characterized
by higher income. In other words, the authors suggest both the existence of poverty and middle-
income traps and the possibility of leaving them for affluence. Brasington etal.(2010) propose a
theoretical model based on human capital accumulation and technological progress: they show
Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI
Get Started for FreeStart Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting
