Free riders and the optimal prize in public‐good funding lotteries

Date01 September 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12460
AuthorPaan Jindapon,Zhe Yang
Published date01 September 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:12891312. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
|
1289
Received: 15 November 2019
|
Accepted: 16 June 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12460
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Free riders and the optimal prize in
publicgood funding lotteries
Paan Jindapon
1
|Zhe Yang
2
1
Department of Economics, Finance, and
Legal Studies, University of Alabama,
Tuscaloosa, Alabama
2
Department of Economics, Wofford
College, Spartanburg, South Carolina
Correspondence
Paan Jindapon, Department of Economics,
Finance, and Legal Studies, University of
Alabama, Tuscaloosa, AL.
Email: pjindapon@ua.edu
Abstract
We prove the existence and uniqueness of an equili-
brium in a game where players, whose preferences
exhibit constant absolute risk aversion or constant
relative risk aversion, contribute to a public good via
lotteryticket purchases. Contrasting models with
risk neutrality, we show that an equilibrium with a
strictly positive amount of the public good may not
exist without a sufficient number of participants who
are not too riskaverse. We show that players who are
more riskaverse purchase fewer lottery tickets and
are more likely to free ride in equilibrium. In fact, it is
possible for free riders to place a larger value on
the public good than do those who contribute. In a
symmetric equilibrium, we show that an upper
bound exists for the amount of the public good,
even though there are infinitely many participants.
Furthermore, we derive a lottery prize that max-
imizes the amount of the public good in a symmetric
equilibrium and find that such a prize always results
in an overprovision of the public good.
1|INTRODUCTION
A lottery is an efficient and popular fundraising mechanism. In 2018, Americans purchased $77.7
billion of lottery tickets in 44 states; 30% of the amount was allocated to fund education and other
social programs.
1
Asiswellknownintheliterature,Morgan's(2000) lottery is more effective in
1
On the basis of the 2018 fiscal year (July 1, 2017June 30, 2018), see La Fleur's 2018 World Lottery Almanac.
providing a public good than the voluntary contribution mechanism (VCM). While positive ex-
ternalities associated with the publicgood dissuade players from contributing in all publicgood
funding mechanisms, a contribution through lottery purchase causes negative externalities by
reducing other players' probabilities of winning. This advantage of using a lottery to fund a public
good is supported by many experiments in the laboratory and in the field.
2
Whether a lottery mechanism dominates an allpay auction depends on the information
structure. Between the two mechanisms, Goeree, Maasland, Onderstal, and Turner (2005)theo-
retically show that an augmented allpay auction dominates the lottery mechanism in a private
value setting, while Corazzini et al. (2010) find experimental evidence to support the lottery me-
chanism in a common value setting. In a complete information setting, Damianov and Peeters
(2018) show in theory that an allpay auction dominates the lottery mechanism, but in the lab the
number of players determines which mechanism is optimal. Like Damianov and Peeters (2018), we
adopt the complete information setting and show that not only the number of players, but the
chosen prize also determines the effectiveness of the lottery mechanism. In addition to the fact that
this setting is less complex than other information structure, it bears more resemblance to many
lottery games in the real world where all lottery buyers place the same valuation on the jackpot.
Even though many studies have extended Morgan's (2000) framework in various directions,
and alternative schemes have been proposed,
3
very little theoretical analysis on risk attitudes in
Morgan's mechanism is available. Specifically, most researchers adopt Morgan's (2000) as-
sumption of quasilinear utility, so that each player's marginal utility from private consumption
is constant, regardless of his wealth or whether he wins a prize. This functional form leads to an
important theoretical result: The amount of the public good provided in equilibrium increases
with the lottery prize.
4
Thus, it is feasible to raise money in any desired amount, provided the
lottery prize is large enough.
In this paper, we propose a framework that allows for concavity in utility functions with
respect to both privateand publicgood consumption. Duncan (2002) is the first to examine the
effect of risk attitude on the amount of the publicgood provision in Morgan's lottery. Using a
CobbDouglas utility function, Duncan shows that there is an upper bound for the amount of
public good that can be provided in equilibrium. Lange et al. (2007b) provide a more formal
approach to analyzing the effect of risk aversion; they prove the existence and uniqueness of
equilibrium in a lottery mechanism where players exhibit constant absolute risk aversion
(CARA). On the basis of their experiment, they find that publicgood contributions decline in
risk aversion which is consistent with their theoretical prediction. To the best of our knowledge,
there is no other theoretical proof of the existence of equilibrium in Morgan's lottery me-
chanism, given riskaverse players.
5
2
For example, see Morgan and Sefton (2000), Lange, List, and Price (2007b), Corazzini, Faravelli, and Stanca (2010), and
Carpenter and Matthews (2017).
3
See Goeree et al. (2005), Lange, List, and Price (2007a), Maeda (2008), Corazzini et al. (2010), Kolmar and Wagener
(2012), Faravelli and Stancab (2012,2014), Franke and Leininger (2014), Kolmar and Sisak (2014), Bos (2011,2016),
Damianov and Peeters (2018), and Ghosh and Stong (2018).
4
See Lemma 5 in Morgan (2000). For example, Morgan and Sefton (2000) assume that each player's utility is
u
wG w βG(, )= + , where
β
is a positive constant called the marginal per capita return. It follows that the amount of
public good in equilibrium is
G
=
Rnβ
nβ
e(1)
(1)
, where
R
is the lottery prize and
n
the number of players, and that
G
e
as
→∞
R
.
5
In the contest literature where there is no publicgood provision, Cornes and Hartley (2012) provide a general
framework for analyzing an equilibrium given heterogeneous riskaverse players. Beyond risk aversion, Treich (2010)
and Jindapon and Whaley (2015) explore the effects of downside risk aversion in contests while Kelsey and Melkonyan
(2018) and Stong (2018) focus on ambiguity aversion.
1290
|
JINDAPON AND YANG

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT