Forecast robustness in macroeconometric models

Published date01 September 2017
AuthorGunnar Bårdsen,Ragnar Nymoen,Dag Kolsrud
Date01 September 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/for.2459
Received: 12 May 2014 Revised: 13 October 2016 Accepted: 7 January 2017
DOI: 10.1002/for.2459
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Forecast robustness in macroeconometric models
Gunnar Bårdsen1Dag Kolsrud2Ragnar Nymoen3
1Department of Economics, Norwegian University
of Science and Technology,Trondheim, Norway;
and Norges Bank
2Research Department, Statistics Norway,Oslo,
Norway
3Department of Economics, University of Oslo,
Norway
Correspondence
Dag Kolsrud, Statistics Norway,P. O. Box 8131
Dep, NO-0033 Oslo, Norway.
Email: dok@ssb.no
Abstract
This paper investigates potential invariance of mean forecast errors to structural
breaks in the data generating process. From the general forecasting literature, such
robustness is expected to be a rare occurrence. With the aid of a stylized macro
model we are able to identify some economically relevant cases of robustness and
to interpret them economically. We give an interpretation in terms of co-breaking.
The analytical results resound well with the forecasting record of a medium-scale
econometric model of the Norwegian economy.
KEYWORDS
co-breaking, dynamic homogeneity, equilibrium correction, forecasting, structural
breaks
1INTRODUCTION
Structural breaks represent a main challenge to economic
forecasting. Such breaks are an important source of forecast
failures in macroeconometric models (see, e.g., Clements &
Hendry, 2002; Eitrheim, Husebø, & Nymoen, 1999; Elliott &
Timmermann, 2008). The vulnerability of model-based fore-
casting is generic. Important parts of the literature therefore
focus on ways of making economic forecasts more robust
to breaks. Forecasts can be robustified either individually
or combined, either automatically (like differencing prior to
modeling) or by means of manual intervention (as with inter-
cept correction). The damage done by structural breaks can
also be reduced if there are effective ways of detecting a
break as early as possible after it has occurred (see, e.g.,
Bårdsen, Eitrheim, Jansen, & Nymoen, 2005, chapter 11;
Castle, Fawcett, & Hendry,2011; Clements & Hendr y, 2011;
Giacomini & Rossi, 2009).
In this paper we consider the properties of forecasts pro-
duced by “traditional” equilibrium-correction models. We
demonstrate how mechanisms in the economy can partially
neutralize effects of future breaks on forecasts generated by a
relevant model of that economy.In terms of econometric con-
cepts, we interpret the mechanisms as examples co-breaking
(see Clements & Hendry, 1999, chapter 9; Hendry &
Massmann, 2007).
A concrete motivation for this paper is conveyed by
Figure 1. The panels show real-time forecasts from March
2007 for some key variables in a macroeconometric model
for Norway (cf. Bårdsen & Nymoen, 2009).1The forecasts
(dashed graphs, with prediction bands) can be compared with
the outcomes (solid graphs) until the end of 2011. Some
forecasts fail after the outbreak of the financial crisis, but
most variables are well forecast after the shocks of 2008
and 2009. Most interesting, though, is the behavior of the
actual data series. While the interest rate drops dramatically
(lower right panel)—corresponding to a postforecast struc-
tural break—the outcomes for inflation and the unemploy-
ment rate (upper left and right panel, respectively) are mostly
unaffected, while other variables such as wagegrowth, import
price inflation and gross domestic product (GDP) growth
converge back toward their prebreak predicted paths.
Several variables in the displayed set of forecasts seem to
be more immune to postforecast breaks than what is taken to
be typical (see Clements & Hendry, 2008). There are many
possible explanations for such seemingly partial robustness
to breaks, for example related to the size of the public sector
and the country’s role as an oil exporter. Also, discretionary
policy might have mitigated the effects of the financial crisis,
since in the standard case one would expect an interest rate
forecast failure to go together with large forecast errors for
unemployment for example, but this is not confirmed by the
graphs.
This paper tries to answer the question whether the
empirical partial robustness in Figure 1 can be established
1The model used is NAM. See http://www.svt.ntnu.no/iso/gunnar.bardsen/
nam/evaluation/index.html for an evaluationof the forecasts.
Journal of Forecasting.2017;36:629–639. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/for Copyright © 2017 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 629

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT