Fit for Purpose and Fit for the Future? An Evaluation of the UK's New Flood Reinsurance Pool

Published date01 March 2018
Date01 March 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rmir.12093
Risk Management and Insurance Review
C
Risk Management and Insurance Review, 2018, Vol.21, No. 1, 33-72
DOI: 10.1111/rmir.12093
PERSPECTIVE
FIT FOR PURPOSE AND FIT FOR THE FUTURE?AN
EVAL UA TI ON O F TH E UK’SNEW FLOOD REINSURANCE
POOL
Swenja Surminski
ABSTRACT
Flood Re is widely hailed as an innovative approach to disaster risk insurance.
This article offers a mixed-methods evaluation of the new pool, asking whether
it is “fit for purpose” and “fit for the future.” The investigation considers the
roles of the public and private sectors, risk modeling and risk communication,
technical underwriting, distributional aspects, and the behavioral implications
of Flood Re, particularly with regards to risk reduction and prevention. The
article concludes that the new pool is a transitional reinsurance arrangement
that supports the private insurance market and secures affordability of flood
insurance in the United Kingdom through premium subsidies. However, this
approach is likely to come under pressure in the face of rising flood risk as it
fails to incentivize flood risk management and risk reduction efforts.
INTRODUCTION
Natural disasters such as drought, flooding, and wind storms cause significant human
and economic losses, affecting communities, businesses, and governments and ham-
pering economic development and poverty reduction efforts. In many countries, such
disasters are becoming more likely with climate change according to projections by
the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (“IPCC”). Moreover, the values at risk
are also becoming even greater due to increasing population concentration and rising
wealth, often in highly exposed coastal locations. These trends have reintensified discus-
sions among private insurers, governments, and international organizations about the
role of insurance in addressing disaster risks. The discourse follows two broad strands:
Swenja Surminski is at the Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment,
London School of Economics. This article was prepared for the “Improving Disaster Financing:
Evaluating Policy Interventions in Disaster Insurance Markets” workshop held at Resources
for the Future on November 29–30, 2016. The author would like to thank the sponsors of this
project: the American Academy of Actuaries, the American Risk and Insurance Association, Risk
Management Solutions, the Society of Actuaries, and XL Catlin. The author also would like to
acknowledge the financial support of the UK Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC)
through the Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy, and of the Grantham Foundation
for the Protection of the Environment through the Grantham Research Institute on Climate
Change and the Environment. The author thanks Joel Hankinson for his input and assistance.
33
34 RISK MANAGEMENT AND INSURANCE REVIEW
reform of existing insurance schemes, such as in the United Kingdom and the United
States; and the design of new schemes in countries without disaster insurance, includ-
ing in developing countries (see, for example, Surminski and Oramas-Dorta, 2014). Such
efforts are based on the understanding that insurance mechanisms offer a more effective
way of addressing the costs of disasters than relying on postdisaster payments (see, for
example, Brainard, 2008; Hallegatte, 2014). The sharing of risks and the distribution of
the costs of compensation make insurance an attractive disaster response mechanism,
particularly for large catastrophic risks (Mechler et al., 2014), but remains underused in
many parts of the world.
In countries that have disaster insurance, this tends to be arranged through the state or
via a partnership approach between the public sector and private insurers, owing to the
complex nature of disaster risks. The affordability and availability of disaster insurance
can become a public policy goal, seeking to ensure that an economically efficient level
of insurance is provided and accessible to those who need it. However, in many cases,
governments face conflicting objectives and aims; in particular, being concerned with
reducing public expenditure on flood losses, but at the same time remaining keen to offer
a “helping hand” in times of flooding. If and how government intervenes in the flood
insurance market therefore depends, at least in part, on a country’s specific risk features,
cultural approach to solidarity and responsibility, political will, as well as recent loss
experiences (Kunreuther et al., 2009).
There are many different ways in which disaster risk insurance can be supported by the
government, ranging from direct premium subsidies to providing financial education.
Table1 shows how possible interventions can target the supply of insurance, the demand
for insurance, or premium levels.
The types of government intervention in disaster insurance markets vary significantly
between countries, ranging from no insurance, to only private or fully public insurance
(Paudel 2012; Lamond and Penning-Rowsell, 2014). For example, while French law re-
quires certain kinds of insurance contracts to cover natural catastrophes and fixes an
additional amount payable by the insured (Maccaferri et al., 2012), the U.K. government
has focused on making flood insurance more affordable by improving reinsurance op-
tions for insurers through its flood reinsurance program, “Flood Re.” While the former
can be considered a more “public” approach to flood insurance, the latter has continued
to rely predominantly on the private market.
One aspect that is growing in importance, but remains often overlooked in the public
policy discourse, is the suitability of insurance mechanisms to cope with changing
risk profiles. This is particularly relevant in the face of rising disaster costs due to
socioeconomic factors and climate change, which can pose a threat to future insurability.
These trends can negatively impact the business model of the insurance industry itself,
potentially making insurance unavailable or unaffordable. Currently, the industry’s best
defense against this is the 1-year contract relationship with clients, which does not require
an assessment of long-term risk, and offers flexibility to amend and adjust price coverage
on an annual basis. However, this is only a short-term defense against rising risk. If
significant efforts are not taken to reduce risk by increasing resilience,costs will continue
to rise and insurers may stop offering climate change-related insurance products, as
noted by the U.K.’s regulator PRA (Prudential Regulation Authority, 2015); indeed,
FIT FOR PURPOSE AND FIT FOR THE FUTURE 35
TABLE 1
Public Disaster Risk Insurance Interventions With the Aim of Increasing Take-Up of Insur-
ance
Target Area Intervention Measure
Supply Set-up state-owned insurer
Provide reinsurance
Provide capital
Pay operational costs
Provide product development expertise and technical support
Promote co-insurance pool
Link to social safety nets and credit facilities
Premium Levels Regulate premiums by setting limits or tariffs
Regulate risk models used
Data collection, audit, management and financing (can lead to higher
premiums)
Provide risk data to insurers (can also lead to higher premiums)
Reduce risk levels through better risk management
Demand Pay premiums in full or part
Offer vouchers for insurance
Offer incentives for insurance
Mandate insurance
Provide risk data / awareness campaigns
Financial education
Promote enabling environment via legal framework and consumer protection
Source: Vivid Economics et al., 2016.
adaptation could feasibly become a prerequisite to receiving insurance (Golnaraghi
et al., 2016).
Purchasing an insurance product can influence the behavior of those at risk. This can
either be in a moral hazard1context, where insurance can lead to more risky behavior,
or as an incentive, where insurance can trigger risk reduction investments or the im-
plementation of prevention measures (see, for example, Kunreuther, 1996; Kunreuther
and Michel-Kerjan, 2009). Despite a renewed interest in risk reduction by policymakers
1Moral hazard occurs when a member of the party acts conversely to the principles set out in
an agreement between those parties. For example, in an insurance contract, the individuals’
motives and behaviour to prevent loss may be reduced if financially protected through a policy,
thus resulting in an increased probability of loss. For more detail on moral hazard, please see
Arrow (1968) and Pauly (1968). This can affect governments, wherethe existence of an insurance
scheme may reduce the urgency to prevent and reduce risks, or at the insured level, where the
purchase of insurance may lead to a false sense of security.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT