Fiscal Policy in Oil‐exporting Countries: The Roles of Oil Funds and Institutional Quality

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12293
Published date01 August 2017
AuthorWee Chian Koh
Date01 August 2017
Fiscal Policy in Oil-exporting Countries: The Roles
of Oil Funds and Institutional Quality
Wee Chian Koh*
Abstract
Oil-exporting countries face challenges in the conduct of fiscal policy owing to volatile oil revenues,
especially in countries with weak institutions. Many oil exporters have established oil funds to delink
government expenditure from oil revenues; however, their effectiveness remains unresolved. This paper
examines the roles of oil funds and institutional quality in reducing fiscal procyclicality and
macroeconomic volatility in 42 oil-exporting countries from 1960 to 2014 using panel vector
autoregression techniques. The results show that oil funds are effective in reducing fiscal procyclicality in
countries with high institutional quality. There is also a reduction in the procyclical bias in those with low
institutional quality but the statistical evidence is weak. Nevertheless, oil funds are associated with
reduced volatility of government consumption and the real exchange rate in countries with low
institutional quality. These findings give credence to the macroeconomic stabilization role of oil funds but
also reinforce the importance of good institutions.
1. Introduction
In spite of the potential benefits that natural resource endowments could bring to
resource-rich countries, the underperformance of economic growth and
unsatisfactory development outcomes are well documented (e.g. Sachs and Warner,
1995; Auty, 2001). This phenomenon is referred to as the “resource curse.”
1
There
are five main explanations of the resource curse: the “Dutch disease” hypothesis
(Corden and Neary, 1982); volatile international resource prices that cause
macroeconomic uncertainty (Lane, 2003); unproductive spending on “white
elephant” projects (Gelb, 1986) and underinvestment in human capital (Gylfason,
2001); procyclical fiscal policies and inappropriate monetary policy frameworks
(Frankel, 2011); and political economy arguments of resource abundance (e.g.
Easterly and Levine, 1997; Tornell and Lane, 1999; Acemoglu et al., 2001). These
problems are even more severe in oil-exporting countries owing to the fact that oil
is a “point-source” and “lootable” resource and hence conflict, corruption, and rent
seeking are more likely compared with diffuse resources (Mehlum et al., 2006;
Arezki and Br
uckner, 2009).
2
In addition, oil exporters are subject to larger terms
of trade shocks and, to some extent, the high macroeconomic volatility in these
*Koh (Corresponding author): Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis (CAMA), Crawford School
of Public Policy, College of Asia & the Pacific, The Australian National University, J. G. Crawford
Building, Lennox Crossing, Acton ACT, 2601, Australia. E-mail: wc.koh@anu.edu.au. Thanks are due to
Warwick McKibbin, Ren
ee Fry-McKibbin, Joshua Chan, Samuel Wills, Shane Johnson, Gan-Ochir
Doojav, and participants at a CAMA Macroeconomics Brown Bag seminar for feedback and suggestions.
The author is also grateful for the detailed comments from an anonymous referee as well as the
Managing Editor, Professor Andy McKay, which helped to improve the manuscript. Acknowledgement is
also due to Inessa Love and Ryan Decker for sharing their codes. This research is supported by the
Centre for Strategic and Policy Studies (CSPS), Brunei Darussalam.
Review of Development Economics, 21(3), 567–590, 2017
DOI:10.1111/rode.12293
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
countries can be attributed to procyclical fiscal policies that amplify the boombust
cycle.
3
Among the policy prescriptions advocated to reduce the dependence on volatile
oil revenues to alleviate fiscal procyclicality, macroeconomic volatility, and limit
Dutch disease symptoms in oil-exporting countries is to set up oil funds, which
gained popularity from the late 1990s.
4
Oil funds fall under the umbrella of
sovereign wealth funds (SWFs). Data from the Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute
(2016) shows the total asset size of SWFs to be about US$7.4 trillion as of June
2016, of which 57% are oil and gas funds. Oil funds are typically set up with the
objective of either saving for the future to address issues with regards to fiscal
sustainability and intergenerational equity, or to smooth fiscal expenditure and
stabilize the economy.
5
As the economic argument goes, governments can smooth
expenditures and prevent excessive macroeconomic volatility by channelling surplus
oil revenues to the oil funds during booms and finance budget deficits during cycle
downturns by transfers from these funds.
6
They are therefore related to a broader
literature on fiscal procyclicality.
7
The fact that fiscal policy is procyclical in
developing countries has been documented in many studies (e.g. Gavin and Perotti,
1997; Kaminsky et al., 2004; Talvi and Vegh, 2005; Ilzetzki and Vegh, 2008).
8
The
same result holds when narrowing the sample to resource-rich countries (Cespedes
and Velasco, 2014) and oil-exporting developing countries (Erbil, 2011). In the
political economy context, Arezki et al. (2011) find that procyclical government
spending in resource-rich countries is moderated by the quality of political
institutions. More generally, Frankel et al. (2013) find that a third of the developing
world have “graduated” from fiscal procyclicality over the past decade (i.e. over the
period 20002009), and the key determinant is institutional quality. Interestingly,
about half of this graduation cohort comprises of oil exporters, the period that
coincides with the proliferation of oil funds.
There are only a handful of papers that quantitatively investigate the importance
of oil funds (or natural resource funds) and institutions on the conduct of fiscal
policy.
9
However, the findings of existing studies are somewhat mixed. Davis et al.
(2001) find that resource funds do not have a significant impact on government
spending and are largely redundant based on 12 selected countries (11 oil exporters
and Chile) from 1965 to 1999. Crain and Devlin (2003) find that resource funds can
in fact increase fiscal spending volatility, particularly in oil-exporting countries.
Ossowski et al. (2008) use a larger panel dataset of 31 countries from 1992 to 2005
and conclude that fiscal outcomes are not due to oil funds but they find that higher
institutional quality is associated with lower correlation between government
revenue and expenditure. Likewise, Bova et al. (2016) do not find evidence that
adopting fiscal rules and resource funds have reduced the procyclical bias in non-
renewable commodity exporters; however, they find that better institutional quality
reduces procyclicality.
In contrast, Shabsigh and Ilahi (2007) use a panel dataset of 15 oil-exporting
countries from 1973 to 2003 and find that oil funds are negatively correlated with
volatility of money, prices and to a lesser extent real exchange rates. Asik (2013)
provides evidence in favor of oil funds in reducing fiscal procyclicality and volatility
of fiscal expenditures in 29 oil-exporting countries from 1980 to 2012 but she does
not find any statistically significant association between fiscal performance and
institutional quality. Coutinho et al. (2014) provide evidence of fiscal procyclicality
in resource-rich countries but the effect is lower when there is a resource fund and
also in more democratic regimes. Sugawara (2014) finds that resource funds
568 Wee Chian Koh
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT