First‐Party Versus Third‐Party Compensation for Automobile Accidents: Evidence From Canada

Published date01 March 2010
AuthorAnne Kleffner,Mary Kelly,Maureen Tomlinson
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6296.2009.01177.x
Date01 March 2010
C
Risk Management and Insurance Review, 2010, Vol.13, No. 1, 21-44
DOI: 10.1111/j.1540-6296.2009.01177.x
FIRST-PARTY VERSUS THIRD-PARTY COMPENSATION
FOR AUTOMOBILE ACCIDENTS:EVIDENCE FROM CANADA
Mary Kelly
Anne Kleffner
Maureen Tomlinson
ABSTRACT
Insurance regimes for compensating losses arising from automobile accidents
vary by jurisdiction, ranging from a pure tort system to a pure no-fault system,
with both systems having well-documented benefits and costs. The majority
of published research focuses on the benefits and costs associated with the
compensation for bodily injury. This article extends the existing literature by
examining the differences between first-party and third-party recovery for both
physical damage and bodily injury losses in Canada. Our comparison of auto
insurance costs per insured vehicle suggests that government-run, pureno-fault
provinces have lower average costs than provinces with private tort and modi-
fied no-fault. Lower costs arise from the elimination of tort costs associated with
noneconomic damages, lower claims settlement costs due to first-party compen-
sation, and scales of economy arising from monopoly power.The second goal of
the article is to examine the impact of first- versus third-party compensation on
the settlement of property damage claims. We analyze the claim files of a large
insurer that operates within both a traditional tort (third-party) environment
and a first-party recovery environment for property damage. We find that in a
first-party recovery regime claims are settled sooner,settlement costs are lower,
and not-at-fault drivers are compensated at a higher rate than in the traditional
tort environment.
Mary Kelly is an Associate Professor in the School of Business & Economics, Wilfrid
Laurier University, Waterloo, Ontario, Canada N2L 3C5; phone: (519) 884-0710, ext. 2551;
e-mail: mkelly@wlu.ca. Anne Kleffner is an Associate Professor in the Haskayne School of Busi-
ness, University of Calgary, Calgary, Alberta, Canada T2N 1N4; phone: (403) 220-8596; e-mail:
Kleffner@ucalgary.ca.Maureen Tomlinson is Manager, Business Services for The Economical In-
surance Group in Kitchener,111 Westmount Road South, Ontario, Canada; phone: (519) 570-8500,
ext. 42502; e-mail: maureen.tomlinson@teig.com. The authors would like to thank the insurance
company executives who provided insight and feedback for this project. We are also grateful
to David Chan for research assistance on the project, Gilles Bernier for helpful comments and
assistance in obtaining data, and the Insurance Bureau of Canada and Manitoba Public Insurance
for providing data. This article was subject to double-blind peer review.
21
22 RISK MANAGEMENT AND INSURANCE REVIEW
INTRODUCTION
Insurance regimes for compensating persons injured in automobile accidents vary across
jurisdictions. On one end of the spectrum are pure tort regimes whereby persons are
compensated for their injuries only if another party is at fault, with payment coming
from the at-fault driver’s liability insurance. The third-party insurer pays for the loss,
and there is no first-party compensation. In contrast, there are pure no-fault regimes
whereby injured parties are fully compensated for their injuries by their own insurer,
even if they are at fault, and have a complete prohibition against any right to sue an
at-fault party. In this regime, the first-party insurer provides compensation.
Dissatisfaction with existing tort regimes led to the development of no-fault insurance
(Lascher, 1999). Proponents of no-fault claimed that it would overcome many of the
inefficiencies and inequities of the existing tort regimes: achieving faster settlement of
claims, lower claim settlement costs, and more accurate compensation for economic
losses (O’Connell, 1989; Keeton and O’Connell, 1965; among others). No-fault regimes
attempt to compensate those injured in accidents without regard to fault, while the aim
of a tort regime is to judge fault accurately and to hold the at-fault party financially
responsible. In short, whereas no-fault regimes place a greater emphasis on compensa-
tion, tort regimes place a greater focus on accountability for negligence. Currently, in
North America, most states and provinces have something in between: auto insurance
provides for some level of first-party benefits for injuries and there may or may not be
some restriction on the right to sue.
Many researchers have described the advantages and disadvantages of both tort and no-
fault regimes and attempted to measure the differences between the two. The majority
of the work has focused on insurance costs and compensation for bodily injury since
no-fault regimes in the United States relate to bodily injury only.1It is an empirical
question whether or not no-fault can help control auto insurance costs. Fundamentally,
costs depend on the level of first-party benefits and the threshold that determines which
parties have the right to sue.
This research adds to the literature by examining two key issues. First, we look at the
relationship between the insurance regime (tort vs. no-fault), market structure (private
vs. government run), and insurance costs for mandatory insurance coverages across
Canada. Wecompare auto insurance costs per insured vehicle in three distinct systems—
government-run pure no-fault, private modified no-fault, and private tort—and find
that government-run pure no-fault has the lowest average cost while private modified
no-fault has the highest cost.
Second, we examine the effect of first- versus third-party recovery for not-at-fault phys-
ical damage losses across two Canadian jurisdictions.2With respect to efficiencies in
first-party versus third-party recovery regimes, our research differs from previous re-
search in that we examine the claim files of a large insurer that operates within both a
traditional tort (third-party recovery) environment and a first-party recovery environ-
ment for not-at-fault property damage. Our focus on physical damage, as opposed to
1The exception is Michigan, which operates under a first-party recovery for property damage
claims.
2At-fault property damage losses to one’s automobile are a first-party coverage in all provinces
in Canada.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT