First‐best health policy in vaccine markets with health and network externalities
Published date | 01 December 2023 |
Author | Rabah Amir,Filomena Garcia,Iryna Topolyan |
Date | 01 December 2023 |
DOI | http://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12673 |
Received: 24 October 2023
|
Accepted: 29 October 2023
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12673
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
First‐best health policy in vaccine markets
with health and network externalities
Rabah Amir
1
|Filomena Garcia
2,3
|Iryna Topolyan
4
1
Department of Economics, The
University of Iowa, Iowa City, Iowa, USA
2
Economics Department, Poole College
of Management, NC State University,
Raleigh, North Carolina, USA
3
UECE, University of Lisbon, Lisbon,
Portugal
4
Department of Economics, University of
Cincinnati, Cincinnati, Ohio, USA
Correspondence
Rabah Amir, Department of Economics,
The University of Iowa, Iowa City,
IA, USA.
Email: rabah-amir@uiowa.edu
Abstract
This paper considers an oligopolistic market for a
vaccine, characterized by negative network effects,
which stem from the free‐riding behavior of indivi-
duals engaged in a vaccination game. Vaccine markets
often suffer from three imperfections: high concentra-
tion, network effects, and a health externality (conta-
gion). The first conclusion of the paper is that the
negative network externality is important as a market
distortion, as it may lead to significant welfare losses.
The second and main part of the paper develops a two‐
part per‐unit subsidy scheme that a social planner
could use to target both consumers and producers of
vaccines. The scope of such a subsidy scheme to induce
the firms to produce the first‐best output without
network effects (which is the most ambitious first‐best
target) is investigated. In many cases, while the first‐
best is attainable, it requires negative prices for
vaccines, which amounts to rewarding consumers to
induce them to vaccinate.
KEYWORDS
health externality, health policy, negative network effects,
pandemics
1|INTRODUCTION
Despite vaccines being widely considered by health professionals as the most effective tool for
the prevention and eradication of infectious diseases, vaccines have always remained a source
of controversy. In fact, the importance of this market for public health officials is often not
J Public Econ Theory. 2023;25:1229–1250. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2023 Wiley Periodicals LLC.
|
1229
matched by people's propensity to vaccinate, despite public awareness and promotion
campaigns for vaccines. For instance, global vaccination coverage is estimated at 80% for
Hepatitis B, 35% for the rotavirus vaccine (against diarrheal diseases, a leading cause of child
mortality), and 47% for yellow fever. For COVID‐19 in the United States, the rate is only 68.6%
in spite of the convenient and free availability of the vaccine. Vaccine hesitancy, as this
phenomenon is often termed, is a potent force that public health officials can simply not afford
to ignore. A historical account and analysis provided by Jana and Osborn (2013) goes as far as
referring to it as vaccinophobia.
1
In light of the direct (financial) and indirect perceived costs of vaccines, one reason behind
these significant gaps in coverage is the recognition that the larger the fraction of vaccinated
people, the less useful vaccines become to those not yet vaccinated, and therefore the lower
their willingness to incur the vaccination costs is. The underlying argument is clearly one of
free‐riding, a conclusion that is a direct implication of simple, agent‐based game‐theoretic
models of vaccination. Brito et al. (1991), Heal and Kunreuther (2005), Adida et al. (2013), and
Sorensen (2023) offer different versions of such games, the common key property of which is
that peoples' decisions to vaccinate are strategic substitutes.
2
A key prediction of these models
is that the fraction of people who opt not vaccinating is increasing the cost of the vaccine. The
notion that these simple models serve as a microfoundation for the fact that vaccine markets
are characterized by negative network effects on the demand side follows naturally and is
explicitly considered in Adida et al. (2013) and Amir et al. (2023).
The pioneering work of Veblen (1899) introduced the notion of bandwagon or positive
network effects in economics long ago. Negative network effects appeared initially as snob
effects in Leibenstein (1950), but were not investigated much in modern times. Nevertheless,
the influential studies by Rohlfs (1974,2001) and Katz and Shapiro (1985) are easily modified to
include the supply side for industries with negative network effects, following recent work by
Amir et al. (2023); also see Nuscheler and Roeder (2016).
The purpose of the present paper is to build on the recent study by Amir et al. (2023) and
provide new results on their model of vaccine markets with negative network effects. We adopt
a simple analog of the model by Katz and Shapiro (1985), with a linear inverse demand whose
intercept shrinks due to additive negative network effects. We adopt the well‐known solution
concept of rational‐expectations Cournot equilibrium (RECE), as in Rohlfs (1974), Katz and
Shapiro (1985), and Amir and Lazzati (2011). In such a setting, both firms and consumers
recognize the presence of negative network externalities and form rational and concordant
expectations as to how the latter affects the equilibrium outcome (also see Amir et al., 2021;
Garcia & Resende, 2011; Shapiro & Varian, 1998).
Exploiting the convenient specification of the model with linear demand and costs, the
unique RECE is easily fully characterized via closed‐form solutions for all variables of interest.
As argued in detail by Amir et al. (2023), the equilibrium properties of this model are consistent
with the main salient stylized facts that pertain to this industry, according to Arnould and
DeBrock (1996), Scherer (2007), and Danzon and Pereira (2011). These stylized facts may be
summarized as follows: (i) a natural monopoly or oligopoly with few firms as a stable market
1
Other relevant accounts may be found in Dasgupta et al. (2021) and Galiani (2022).
2
Just to mention some examples, Nganmeni et al. (2022) offer a cooperative games perspective. Hellmann and Thiele
(2022) consider voluntary testing and self‐isolation. Gallic et al. (2022) investigate the timing effects of vaccine arrival
on the optimal social‐distancing policy (see also Goenka et al., 2022; Makris, 2021). Finally, Federico et al. (2022)
consider optimal vaccination within a SIR model.
1230
|
AMIR ET AL.
Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI
Get Started for FreeStart Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting
