Fearlessly Swimming Upstream to Risky Waters: The Role of Geographic Entry in Innovation

AuthorRaja Roy,Timothy David Hubbard,Minyoung Kim,Curba Morris Lampert,George Leckie
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12347
Published date01 November 2019
Date01 November 2019
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd and S ociety for the Advancement of Ma nagement Studies
Fearlessly Swimming Upstream to Risky Waters: The Role
of Geographic Entry in Innovation
Curba Morris Lampert, Minyoung Kim,
Timothy David Hubbard, Raja Roy and George Leckie
Florida International University; University of Kansas; University of Notre Dame; New Jersey
Institute of Technology; University of Bristol
ABST RACT We examine the puzzli ng geographic pattern t hat shows firms enteri ng
countries with weak i ntellectual property r ights (IPR) protection with their research
and development (R&D) activities. Geogr aphic entry into weak IPR protection coun-
tries is at odds w ith conventional wisdom as such an env ironment erodes a firm's ability
to appropriate from its innovat ions. We offer that while the well- established pract ice of
spreading out a firm's value chai n activities ac ross a region has import ant implications
for value creation, what remains un addressed is the v alue appropriation aspect of such
activities. We introduce a multi level theory and mainta in that operating regionally
through commercializat ion activities (downstream activities) provides complementary
assets to the upst ream activities – specifica lly R&D activities in a country w ithin that region
– with which focal f irms can appropriate more from their innovations. We f ind that
regional downstrea m commercialization activities ca n substitute for weak IPR regimes ,
thereby providing fir ms with an alternative mechanism for protecti ng their intellectual
property in weak IPR countr ies.
Key words : complementarities, geographic entr y, innovation, R&D, upstream and
downstream act ivities, value appropri ation
INTRODUCTION
Innovation is a diff icult process, demanding that firms keep pace with technolog-
ical changes while avoiding overly repeating and exhausting recombinant oppor-
tunities (Fleming, 2001). Geographic entry into foreign markets through research
and development (R&D) activities can allow firms to access global resources to
Journal of Man agement Studi es 56:7 November 2019
doi:10.1111/j oms .12 347
Address for reprints: Curba Morris Lampert , College of Busines s, Florida I nternational Univers ity,
11200 Southwest 8th Street, M iami, FL 33199, USA (curba.lampert@f iu.edu)
1378 C. M. Lampert et al.
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd and S ociety for the Advancement of Ma nagement Studies
assist in their innovation processes (Almeida, 1996; Almeida and Kogut, 1999;
Doz and Wilson, 2012; Florida, 1997; Frost, 2001; Jaffe et al., 1993; Nelson, 1993;
Patel and Vega, 1999; Pearce, 1999; Zhao, 2006). An analysis by Goldman Sachs
offers economic evidence that the global distribution of research and scientific
activity is shi fting, suggesting a ‘changing and more global innovation landscape’
(Gilman, 2010, p. 3). As new hubs of innovative activity are emerging, and across
a range of industries – including automotive, electronics, IT consulting and ser-
vices, net working a nd communication dev ices, pharmaceutic als, a nd semicon-
ductors – it presents an opportunity for firms to rethi nk where they want to invest
their innovative activities (Gilman, 2010).
Recent instances of geographic entry into foreign countries through R&D activ-
ities by firms reflect the economic evidence. For example, Pfizer is investing $14
million in Chile to launch a Center of Excellence in Precision Medicine (CEPM),
which will focus on developing new genome-based diagnostic technologies for can-
cer (Leask, 2015). Sylvia Varela, president of Pfizer Oncology for Latin America,
explains ‘the work that will be done at CEPM will be on par with the best and most
renowned research centres in the world’ (Leask, 2015). Apple is investing $1 bil-
lion in a new R&D centre in Vietnam, joining the high-profile firms of Samsung
Electronics, Hewlett-Packard, and Panasonic, which have made significant invest-
ments in R&D centres there as well (Maylay Mail Online, 2016; Tuyet, 2016). Intel
chose Costa Rica to host its newest R&D ‘mega lab’, which will develop new smart-
phones, tablets, laptops, desktops, and all-in-one computers for its global custom-
ers (Arias, 2015a, 2015b; Costa Rican Investment Promotion Agency, 2014).
A primary reason for studying the role of geographic entry in innovation has
been to understand how firms can use geographic entry as a source of value cre-
ation. Geographic entry into foreign markets can allow firms the opportunity
to potentially access resources to fuel their innovative processes, including new
and diverse sources of knowledge (Almeida, 1996; Frost, 2001; Pearce, 1999),
high-quality scientists, engineers, and designers (Florida, 1997; Zhao, 2006), dif-
ferent national innovation systems (Freeman, 1987; Lundvall, 1992; Nelson, 1993;
Patel and Vega, 1999) and knowledge spillovers (Almeida and Kogut, 1999; Jaffe
et al., 1993), many of which are only reachable by being in distinct, host locations
(Birkinshaw, 2000; Cantwell, 1989; Dunning, 1998; Frost, 2001; Kogut, 1991).
Returning to our aforementioned examples, a firm's geographic entry into the
foreign markets of Chile, Vietnam, or Costa Rica can offer location-specific advan-
tages leading to enhanced value creation for the firm.
However, the performance of a firm's R&D investment is a joint function of
value creation and value appropriation. In this light, what is striking about Chile,
Vietnam, and Costa Rica is that they are all countries that do not have strong in-
tellectual property rights (IPR) protection. As R&D activities are subject to risks
of knowledge leakage and threats of imitation from global exposure, firms may
not be able to appropriate the economic return from the value they create in
such countries (Teece, 1986). This makes the empirical patterns of geographic
entry into the weak IPR protection countries all the more perplexing. Thus, in
Fearlessly Swimming Upstream to Risky Waters 1379
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd and S ociety for the Advancement of Ma nagement Studies
understanding the role of geographic entry in innovation there remains the un-
resolved question of how do firms appropriate the value they create from their R&D
activities in such weak appropriability regime countries?
In this paper, we seek an answer to this research question and attempt to explain
the recent, puzzling geographic patterns that show firms entering their R&D ac-
tivities into countries with weak IPR protection. Geographic entry into weak IPR
countries is at odds with conventional wisdom as such an environment erodes
firms’ ability to appropriate from their innovations. We combine the technology
management literature's complementary assets framework (Mitchell, 1989, 1991;
Teece, 1986; Tripsas, 1997) with the international management literature's re-
gionalization theory and semi-globalization perspective (Ghemawat, 2003, 2005;
Rugman and Verbeke, 2004, 2007) to develop a new theoretical model of the
role of geographic entry in innovation. Joining the two streams of theories not
only helps us to address the research question but also results in explanatory
power gains from the cross-fertilization, which facilitates a new exchange in a
now shared conversation across the technology management and international
management literatures.
Toward this end, we first conceptualize geographic entry into a region as the re-
gional configuration of complementary assets, or the geographic dispersion of a firm's
value chain activities across countries within a region. With this conceptualization,
we offer that while the well-established practice of spreading out a firm's value
chain activities across a region has important implications for value creation, what
remains unaddressed is the value appropriation aspect of such activities. We intro-
duce a multilevel theory and maintain that operating regionally through commer-
cialization activities (downstream activities) provides complementary assets to the
upstream activities – specifically R&D activities in a country within that region – with
which the focal firm can appropriate more from its innovations. More specifically,
we develop a framework that suggests that commercialization activities in the re-
gion help firms develop a firm-specific value appropriation capability that allows
them to appropriate more from their innovation activities even in the countries
within the region with weak IPR protections. We submit that regional downstream
commercialization activities can substitute for weak IPR regimes, thereby provid-
ing the firm with an alternative mechanism for protecting its intellectual property
in weak IPR countries.
We test our theory using a dataset of innovative activity in the global pharmaceuti-
cal industry encompassing 142 multinational enterprises (MNEs) operating in 118
countries within 18 geographic regions. This dataset accounts for all of the sam-
ple firms’ drug commercialization activity and R&D activity worldwide. We employ
a cross-classified multilevel analysis to simultaneously account for the firm, coun-
try, and regional levels of analysis and answers calls for more multilevel research
(Arregle et al., 2006; Cheng et al., 2009; Hitt et al., 2007; Peterson et al., 2012).
Our theory and findings contribute to the literature in three ways. First, we illu-
minate the role of geographic entry in innovation as the regional configuration of

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT