Fairness in tax compliance: A political competition model

AuthorÁngel Solano‐Garcia
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12232
Date01 October 2017
Published date01 October 2017
Received: 12 June 2016 Accepted: 24 July 2016
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12232
ARTICLE
Fairness in tax compliance: A political
competition model
Ángel Solano-Garcia
Universityof Granada
ÁngelSolano-Garcia, Departamento de Teorí e
HistoriaEconómica, Universidad de Granada,
18011Granada, Spain (asolano@ugr.es).
Iwould like to thank Enriqueta Aragonès, Hum-
bertoLlavador, Santiago Sanchez-Pages, Socorro
Puy,and Ascension Andina for their helpful com-
ments.I acknowledge financial support from
SpanishMinistery of Economy and Competitive-
ness,grant numbers ECO2013-44879-R and ECO
2014-57673-REDT.The usual caveat applies.
This paper analyzes the political economy of income redistribution
when voters are concerned about fairness in tax compliance. We
consider a two-stage model where there is a two-party competition
overthe tax rate and over the intensity of the tax enforcement policy
in the first stage, and voters decide about their level of tax compli-
ance in the second stage. We find that if the concern about fairness
in tax compliance is high enough, a liberal middle-income majority of
voters may block any income redistribution policy.Alternatively, we
find an equilibrium in which the preferences of the median voter are
ignored in favor of a coalition formed by a group of relatively poor
voters and the richest voters. In this equilibrium income redistribu-
tion prevails with no tax enforcement.
“I'll bet a million dollars against any member of the Forbes400 who challenges me that the average (federal tax
rate including income and payroll taxes)for the Forbes 400 will be less than the average of their receptionists.”–
WarrenBuffett, 20071
1INTRODUCTION
In the midst of the recent debt crisis, tax compliance has been a hot issue in many parliaments of developedcountries.
For instance, Mitt Romney's case of tax avoidanceintroduced another dimension into the debate about income taxes
in the 2012 U.S. elections. The importance of tax compliance in politics is even more intense in European countries
with financing problems in such countries as Greece, Portugal, Ireland, Spain, and Italy. While millions of citizens are
required by their governments to bear the burden of heavy tax hikes, recent news reports have unveiledimportant
cases of tax evasion, tax avoidance, and tax fraud by politicians and large fortunes in these countries (see the case of
the Barcenas scandal,2Lagarde's list, or the Spanish tax amnesty for some examples). This misbehavior affects public
opinion on society's tax morale which may result in voters'shiftingtheir preferences for income redistribution.
The aim of this paper is to study the political economy of income redistribution when voters are concerned about
fairness in tax compliance. We consider a two-stage model where there is two-party competition overthe tax rate and
1Forthe full interview with Warren Buffett see http://www.cnbc.com/id/21553857
2Forsome reviews of the case see http://www.nytimes.com/2013/02/01/world/europe/prime-minister-of-spain-accused-of-receiving-payouts.html?_r=0
Journal of Public Economic Theory.2017;19:1026–1041. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet c
2017 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. 1026
SOLANO-GARCIA 1027
over the levelof tax enforcement in the first stage, and voters decide about their level of tax compliance in the second
stage. Regarding tax noncompliance, we focus on tax evasion rather than on tax avoidance since tax evaderswho are
detected have to pay a penalty.3Inour framework, the possibility of tax evasion adds a way of redistributing income
from the poor to the rich that is opposite to traditional taxation models. These two opposing ways of redistributing
income turn middle-income voters into the highest net contributors to welfare policies: They are subsidizing both the
poor by the traditional redistributive channel, and the rich by the channel associated with tax evasion. Wefind that if
fairness concern in tax compliance is large enough, a majority of middle-income voters may block any income redis-
tribution policy. Alternatively,a coalition of the poorest and the richest voters in favor of income redistribution but
against any tax enforcement policy can also be a feasible equilibrium.
There is vast literature on tax compliance (for excellent surveys,see Andreoni, Brian, & Feinstein, 1998; Slemrod,
2007; Slemrod & Yitzhaki, 2002). Most of the studies in the literature are based on the frameworkproposed by Alling-
ham and Sandmo (1972) in which taxpayers maximize their expected utility under the probability of a penalty if they
are caught underreporting their taxable income. This deterrence theory has been criticized by many authors because
it predicts a much lower compliance rate than what we actually observe (see Alm, McClelland, & Schulze, 1992; Feld&
Frey,2002; Graetz & Wild, 1985).
Behavioralmodels that assume some tax morale in taxpayers try to solve this empirical problem. For instance, Erard
and Feinstein(1994) proposed a model in which tax noncompliance produces feelings of guilt and shame that are incor-
porated exogenouslyin taxpayers'utility function. Gordon (1989) addressed the topic of fairness and tax compliance.
He made the psychic cost of tax evasionendogenous in a dynamic model in which this psychic cost varies inversely with
the number of individuals evading in the previous period. A similar approach was suggested in Bordignon (1993), who
considered that individuals'decisions about tax compliance depend on what they consider is fair,which in turn would
depend on their conjectures about the aggregated level of tax compliance. More recently,Taxler (2010) incorporated
tax morale into the Allingham and Sandmo (1972) model. His study underlined the role of beliefs about others'levelof
tax compliance in shaping the relationship between tax enforcement and tax evasion.
Other papers have focused on the effect of corruption and waste of resources by the government on tax compli-
ance. Pommerehne, Hart, and Frey (1994) presented a dynamic model in which taxpayer compliance decreases with
deviation between the individual's optimal choice of public good provision and the one implemented, noncompliance
by other taxpayers,and the level of government waste in the previous period.
Empirically, Spicer and Becker (1980) supported the premise that fairness is important for tax compliance. They
experimentally found that individuals'decisions about tax evasion depend on the relative comparison between their
payments and others'payments. Other more recent empirical papers such as Cummings, Martinez-Vazquez,McKee,
and Torgler(2009), Frey and Torgler(2007), and Torgler (2002 and 2005) found a significant relationship between tax
compliance, tax morale, and trust in public institutions.
Followingthe approach of these behavioral models and empirical results, we assume that individuals are concerned
about fairness in tax compliance. More precisely,we assume that taxpayers suffer a psychic cost of deviating from the
expected averagelevel of tax compliance. Our main findings are as follows.
We find that voters'preferences on both policy instruments heavily depend on their sensitivity to the social cost
of tax evasion, as well as their perception about the wasting of public funds. Regardless of the analysis of other cases,
throughout the paper we focus on the scenario in which the latter voters'characteristicsare important enough. In this
context, we obtain that preferences for income redistribution are nonmonotonic in taxpayers'income, with middle-
income voters being against income redistribution and votersin the extremes of the income distribution being in favor.
This result contrasts with the classical result that preferences for income redistribution are decreasing in income
(see Meltzer & Richard, 1981). Introducing the possibility of tax evasion changes the way income is redistributed
through income tax with respect to the traditional models. In traditional taxation models, poor voters prefer a high
income tax in order to extract income from the rich. Including the possibility of tax evasion makes the poor prefer a
3Weare aware that the distinction between tax evasion and tax avoidance sometimes becomes blurred, especially when dealing with individuals at the topof
theincome redistribution.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT