Factor Endowments, Democracy, and Trade Policy Divergence

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12057
Date01 February 2014
Published date01 February 2014
FACTOR ENDOWMENTS,DEMOCRACY,AND TRADE POLICY
DIVERGENCE
SEBASTIAN GALIANI
Washington University in St. Louis
NORMAN SCHOFIELD
Washington University in St. Louis
GUSTAVO TORRENS
Washington University in St. Louis
Abstract
We develop a stochastic model of electoral competition in
order to study the economic and political determinants of
trade policy. We model a small open economy with two
tradable goods, each of which is produced using a sector-
specific factor (e.g., land and capital) and another factor
that is mobile between these tradable sectors (labor); one
nontradable good, which is also produced using a specific
factor (skilled labor), and an elected government with the
mandate to tax trade flows. The tax revenue is used to pro-
vide local public goods that increase the economic agents’
utility. We use this general equilibrium model to explic-
itly derive the ideal policies of the different socioeconomic
Sebastian Galiani, Department of Economics, Washington University in St. Louis, Campus
Box 1208, One Brookings Drive, St. Louis, MO 63130-4899, USA (galiani@wustl.edu). Nor-
man Schofield, Department of Political Science, Washington University in St. Louis, Cam-
pus Box 1207, One Brookings Drive, St. Louis, MO 63130-4899, USA (schofield.norman@
gmail.com). Gustavo Torrens, Department of Economics, Washington University in St.
Louis, Campus Box 1208, One Brookings Drive, St. Louis, MO 63130-4899, USA (gftor-
rens@go.wustl.edu).
We appreciate very helpful comments from two anonymous referees, Daniel Heymann,
David Levine, Paulo Somaini, Donald Saari, and participants at World Congress of the
Econometric Society 2010, the International Conference on Political Economy and Insti-
tutions 2010, APET Meeting 2010, Annual Meeting of DEGIT 2010, and Annual Meeting
of LACEA 2010, the Meeting of SAET, 2011, and seminar participants at World Bank,
Washington University in St. Louis, and Universidad de San Andr´
es. Norman Schofield
acknowledges financial support from NSF grant 0715929 and Sebastian Galiani acknowl-
edges financial support from ESRC grant 062-23-1360.
Received November 17, 2010; Accepted January 18, 2012.
C2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16 (1), 2014, pp. 119–156.
119
120 Journal of Public Economic Theory
groups in society (landlords, industrialists, labor, and skilled
workers). We then use those ideal policies to model the indi-
vidual probabilistic voting behavior of the members of each
of these socioeconomic groups. We use this model to shed
light on how differences in the comparative advantages of
countries explain trade policy divergence between countries
as well as trade policy instability within countries. We regard
trade policy instability to mean that, in equilibrium, polit-
ical parties diverge in terms of the political platforms they
adopt. We show that in natural resource (land)–abundant
economies with very little capital, or in economies that spe-
cializes in the production of manufactures, parties tend to
converge to the same policy platform, and trade policy is
likely to be stable and relatively close to free trade. In con-
trast, in a natural resource–abundant economy with an im-
portant domestic industry that competes with the imports,
parties tend to diverge, and trade policy is likely to be more
protectionist and unstable.
1. Introduction
Many developing countries adopted trade protectionist measures during the
second part of the 20th century. Most of these countries, if not all of them,
did not have a comparative advantage in the manufacturing sector and they
did not industrialize in a sustainable way as a result. Instead, they had a
comparative advantage within the primary sector. In contrast, countries with
comparative advantage in the manufacturing sector tended to remain much
more open to trade. In addition, the countries that adopted import substitu-
tion policies tended to show substantial volatility over time in their trade poli-
cies. In this paper, we develop a stochastic model of electoral competition to
study the economic and political determinants of trade policy. Our goal is to
provide an explanation of the variability of trade policy both across countries
and within a country over time, rather than across industrial sectors.
Many models of political choice emphasize political convergence to an
electoral mean or median. Although extremely useful to study important
questions in the field of political economy, such models appear to be of lim-
ited use in explaining the oscillations that can occur as a result of divergent
political choices by parties. Schofield (2007) suggests, however, that politi-
cal parties will not converge if there is sufficient difference in the valences of
political leaders, where the valence of a candidate captures all the character-
istics of the candidate and the party that affect voting decisions and are not
related with policy platforms. Furthermore, in this version of the stochastic
model, there is convergence or divergence depending on pure political fac-
tors, such as the difference in the valances of the candidates, as well as on
the distribution of voters’ policy preferences, which ultimately depends on
structural characteristics of the economy.
Factor Endowments, Democracy, and Trade Policy Divergence 121
We model a small open economy with two tradable goods, each of which
is produced using a sector-specific factor (land and capital) and a third fac-
tor (e.g., labor) which is mobile between these tradable sectors. There is also
one nontradable good, which is produced using a specific factor (skilled la-
bor). The political model has an elected government with the mandate to fix
an ad valorem import tax rate. The tax revenue is used to provide two local
public goods. One public good is targeted at the specific factors of produc-
tion whereas the other is targeted at the mobile factor of production. We
use this general equilibrium model to derive the ideal policies of the differ-
ent socioeconomic groups in society (landlords, industrialists, workers, and
service workers). We then use those derived ideal policies to model the indi-
vidual probabilistic voting behavior of the members of each of these socioe-
conomic groups. The combined model is thus based on micropolitical econ-
omy foundations of citizens’ preferences. We believe this paper is the first
to employ this methodology in order to study how differences in the factor
endowments of countries explain trade policy divergence between countries
as well as trade policy instability within countries.
Just as in Grossman and Helpman (1994,1996), we consider two inter-
connected sources of political influence: electoral competition and interest
groups. In their study of the political economy of protection, Grossman and
Helpman proposed a model of protection in which economic interests orga-
nize along sectoral lines, so that interest groups form to represent industries.
Their model predicts a cross-sectional structure of protection, depending on
political and economic characteristics, and provides an excellent model of
within country cross-section variability of trade policy. In contrast, we focus
on the variability of trade policy both across countries and within a country
over time, rather than across sectors.
Our work is related to the analysis of Rogowski (1987,1989) on the ef-
fects of international trade on political alignments (see also Baldwin 1989).
Rogowski (1987) elaborates a lucid explanation of political cleavages, as
well as changes in those cleavages over time as a consequence of exoge-
nous shocks in the risk and cost of foreign trade. Rogowski (1987) classifies
economies according to their factor endowments of capital, land, and labor,
and uses his classification to deduce two main types of political cleavages:
a class cleavage and an urban–rural cleavage. The model that we present
includes nontradable goods and this allows for a richer characterization
of political alignments. In particular, in natural resource (land)–abundant
economies, without the inclusion of nontradable goods, landlords favor free
trade, and industrialists and workers are protectionist, inducing an urban–
rural cleavage. However, once nontradable goods are introduced in the
model, distributive conflict among urban groups will also be present. Indus-
trialists and unskilled workers may favor protectionist policies while skilled
workers favor free trade policies (see Galiani, Heymann, and Magud 2009).
Furthermore, we show that the presence of a distributive conflict between

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT