EXPLOITING CLOSED‐END FUND DISCOUNTS: A SYSTEMATIC EXAMINATION OF ALPHAS

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12122
Published date01 June 2017
AuthorYangru Wu,Louis R. Piccotti,Dilip Patro
Date01 June 2017
EXPLOITING CLOSED-END FUND DISCOUNTS:
A SYSTEMATIC EXAMINATION OF ALPHAS
Dilip Patro
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
Louis R. Piccotti
University at Albany, State University of New York
Yangru Wu
Rutgers Business School
Abstract
We systematically study the value of the information contained in closed-end fund
(CEF) premiums. We parametrically estimate CEF expected returns as a function of the
history of CEF premiums, in addition to the current premium, and buy the quintile of
funds with the highest expected returns and sell the quintile of funds with the lowest
expected returns. The return on this portfolio suggests that previous studies, which
examine the information in current premiums only, have understated the value of the
information in premiums. Our strategy values the information in the history of CEF
premiums at an annualized return of 18.2%.
JEL Classification: G01, G11, G12
I. Introduction
Closed-end funds (CEFs) are investment companies that issue a f‌ixed number of shares
and invest the proceeds based on the objective of the fund. The shares of a CEF are traded
on a stock exchange similar to common stock and unlike an open-end fund cannot be
redeemed by the shareholders at its net asset value (NAV). In eff‌icient and frictionless
markets, the share price at which a fund trades must equal its NAV. In reality, however,
share prices are often signif‌icantly below their respective NAVs (termed the CEF
discount puzzle). Furthermore, the difference between share prices and NAVs, referred
to as the premium,
1
exhibits large time-series and cross-sectional variation. A large body
We thank the editor, two anonymous referees, Ren-raw Chen, Bjorn Flesaker, George Jiang, Andreas
Michlmayr, Robert Patrick, David Smith, Daniel Weaver, Fei Wu, Feng Zhao, the editors, two anonymous referees,
and seminar and conference participants at Rutgers University, Central University of Finance and Economics, City
University of New York, and the International Symposium on Financial Engineering and Risk Management for
helpful conversations and comments. Part of this work was completed while Wu visited the Chinese Academy of
Finance and Development of the Central University of Finance and Economics, whose hospitality was greatly
appreciated. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily ref‌lect those of their
institutions. We are responsible for any remaining errors.
1
A funds discount is the negative of its premium.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XL, No. 2 Pages 223248 Summer 2017
223
© 2017 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
of research has tried to explain this puzzling behavior. Leading explanations include
investor sentiment effects (see, e.g., De Long et al. 1990; Lee, Shleifer, and Thaler 1991),
open-ending frictions (see, e.g., Brickley and Schallheim 1985; Bradley et al. 2010;
Brauer 1988), agency costs (see, e.g., Barclay, Holderness, and Pontiff 1993; Khorana,
Wahal, and Zenner 2002; Del Guercio, Dann, and Partch 2003), managerial skills (Chay
and Trzcinka 1999; Coles, Suay, and Woodbury 2000; Johnson, Lin, and Song 2006;
Berk and Stanton 2007), and market segmentation (see, e.g., Bonser-Neal et al. 1990;
Bodurtha, Kim, and Lee 1995; Gemmill and Thomas 2002; Nishiotis 2004; Cherkes,
Sagi, and Stanton 2009; Froot and Ramadorai 2008; Elton et al. 2013).
Thompson (1978) f‌inds that portfolios of CEFs trading at discounts outperform
the market and Pontiff (1995) shows that funds with premiums accrue negative
abnormal returns and funds with discounts accrue positive abnormal returns. The
traditional longshort strategy, which sorts on the observed premium alone, ignores
the informationcontent that past CEF premiums contain, however. Therefore,if the history
of premiums contain valuableinformation, previous studies have understated the value of
information contained in premiums. We contribute to the literature by using a parametric
method to optimallyexploit the information containedin the history of CEF premiums and
premium innovations. Our f‌irst model relieves the traditional assumptions of Thompson
(1978) and Pontiff(1995) that expected returns are exactly the negative of the currentCEF
premium and allows the coeff‌icient on CEF premium to be freely estimated. Our second
model further incorporatesthe optimally chosen history of CEF premiumchanges (similar
to the DickeyFuller, 1981, model) to better match the CEF return-data-generating
process. By estimating thesetwo new models of CEF premiums, we are able to gauge the
value of the information content contained in current premiums, as well as in lagged
premiums, when we form portfolios sorted on our model-predicted expected returns.
First, we f‌ind that the majority of funds exhibit signif‌icant mean reversion in the
premium. Our analysis shows that the bias-adjusted speed for mean reversion to
equilibrium premium levels is 8.6% per month, implying an average half-life of
7.7 months for all the funds in our sample. Furthermore, there exists large cross-sectional
variation in the reversion speeds, indicating substantial heterogeneity across funds. In
general, funds investing in f‌ixed-income securities have faster speeds of reversion than
funds investing in equities. International funds exhibit more signif‌icant evidence of mean
reversion than funds invested domestically. Even for funds within the same fund type,
there exists large cross-sectional heterogeneity in premium mean reversion speeds. Early
explanations for why fund premiums should mean revert are provided by the noise trader
model of De Long et al. (1990) and the investor sentiment hypothesis of Lee, Shleifer,
and Thaler (1991). Alternatively, premiums should also display rational mean reversion
as a result of time-varying contingent liabilities as evidenced in the f‌indings of Malkiel
(1977), Chay, Choi, and Pontiff (2006), and Day, Li, and Xu (2011).
We design a trading strategy that optimally exploits the information content of
CEF premiums by using our two parametric models and then by buying the quintile of
funds with the highest expected returns and selling the quintile of funds with the lowest
expected returns. The returns to this strategy implicitly measure the value contained in
current CEF premiums only and in the history of CEF premium innovations at an
annualized mean return of 17.3% and 18.2%, respectively. Furthermore, commonly used
224 The Journal of Financial Research

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT