Experimental evidence on tax salience and tax incidence

AuthorFrancesco Nemore,Andrea Morone,Simone Nuzzo
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12295
Date01 August 2018
Published date01 August 2018
Received: 8 November2016 Revised: 7 March 2018 Accepted:7 March 2018
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12295
ARTICLE
Experimental evidence on tax salience and tax
incidence
Andrea Morone Francesco Nemore Simone Nuzzo
Universitàdegli Studi di Bari Aldo Moro
AndreaMorone, Dipartimento di Economia,
Managemente Diritto dell'Impresa, Uni-
versitàdegli Studi di Bari Aldo Moro, Largo
AbbaziaSanta Scolastica 53, 70124, Bari, Italy
(andrea.morone@uniba.it).
FrancescoNemore, Dipartimento di Econo-
mia,Management e Diritto dell'Impresa, Uni-
versitàdegli Studi di Bari Aldo Moro, Largo
AbbaziaSanta Scolastica 53, 70124, Bari, Italy
(francesco.nemore@outlook.it).
SimoneNuzzo, Dipartimento di Economia, Man-
agemente Diritto dell'Impresa, Università degli
Studidi Bari Aldo Moro, Largo Abbazia Santa Sco-
lastica53, 70124, Bari, Italy; and Centro di ricerca
sull'economiadei paesi in transizione, Universiteti
KatolikZoja e Këshillit të Mirë, Tirana, Albania
(simone.nuzzo@uniba.it).
Although a basic theoretical principle in public economics assumes
that individuals optimize fully with respect to the introduction of
a tax, a growing body of research is proving that several heuristics
are in place when people take decisions. We re-examine the well
known liability side equivalence principle in the light of the concept
of salience. While these two topics have been extensively investi-
gated in isolation, this paper innovates on the previous literature in
that it focuses on their joint effects. Is tax incidence dependent on
whetherthe subjects face a salient rather than a nonsalient tax? Does
the salience of a tax exert a different effect depending on who is
legally committed to bear the tax burden? We address these ques-
tionsthrough a laboratory experiment in which one unit of a fictitious
good is being traded through a double-auction market institution.
Based on a panel data analysis, our contribution shows that point
of collection matters and determines the economic incidence of tax.
Additionally, we find that the joint effect of salience and statutory
incidence does not alter the informative efficiency, but has a posi-
tive effect on buyers’ allocational efficiency when the tax is leviedon
sellers.
1INTRODUCTION
Taxsalience and the implication of tax perception was first recognized by John Stuart Mill (1848), who stated that
Perhaps the money which [the taxpayer] is required to pay directly out of his pocket is the only tax-
ation which he is quite sure that he pays at all. If all taxes were direct, taxation would be much more
perceived than at present; and there would be a security which now there is not, for economy in the pub-
lic expenditure.
Sausgruber and Tyran(2005) investigated whether the incorrect perception of the tax can translate into distorted
fiscal choices by using a referendum mechanism. This tax misperception can be traced to the so-called phenomenon of
fiscal illusion, which more generally suggests that, when government revenues are not completely transparentor are
582 c
2018 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet Journal of Public Economic Theory.2018;20:582–612.
MORONEET AL.583
not fully perceived by taxpayers, the cost of government is seen to be less expensivethan it actually is. They showed
that subjects who are experienced with one tax regime make better decisions in the other tax regime than subjects
without such experience. Therefore, the direct tax regime leads to correct tax perception.
In a seminal paper,Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2009) studied the impact of tax salience on consumers’ price percep-
tion as well as the subsequent effect on the demand for the taxed goods. The authors implemented a field experiment
at a Northern California grocery: while preserving the usual practice of posting tax-exclusiveprices for control group
products, the authors posted a tag reporting tax-inclusive prices below the original price tag for treatment group prod-
ucts. As a main result, Chetty et al. (2009) found that consumers were less prone to buy those products for which
the tax-inclusive price was shown. More interestingly, giventhe demand price elasticity, they found that the demand
reduction induced by showing tax-inclusive prices was roughly the same as that induced by a price increase equal to
the excluded sales tax from the shelf.As a consequence, the only plausible conclusion was that consumers simply did
not account for the tax scheme in making their purchasing decisions. In other words, the less salient the tax was, the
less it was accounted for.
Several papers report findings that are consistent with those of Chetty et al. (2009) (see, e.g., Finkelstein, 2009;
Gallagher & Muehlegger,2008; Sausgruber & Tyran, 2008, 2011). Then, the main insight we learn from this literatureis
that people overweight more prominent information, with the consequence that when the tax is less salient it induces
a smaller response in subjects’ behavior.
Our contribution re-examines the well known liability side equivalence (LSE) principle in the light of the concept of
tax salience, which is the extent to which taxes are visibleto taxpayers. While these two topics have been extensively
investigated in isolation, this paper innovates on the previous literature in that it focuses on their joint effects. Does
the level of tax salience or tax visibility matter toward the determination of economic incidence of an excisetax? Does
LSE continue to hold with the variation in the level of tax salience? Since salience and statutory incidence should not
provide unlike distributional outcomes taking them in isolation we expect that any interaction among them will not
impact on the informative and allocational efficiency of the market.
Taxincidence is nowadays one of the most debated issues in public economics. The relevance of the topic comes
from the fact that, in order to study the distributional effect of a tax system, it becomes crucial to understand who ulti-
mately suffers the burden of the tax. In this sense, the LSE principle holds that the burden of a unit tax on buyers and
sellers is independent of who actually pays the tax. In the Handbook of Public Economics, Fullerton and Metcalf (2002)
distinguish between “economic incidence” and “statutory incidence”:that is, the person who is legally committed to
pay the tax may not be the person who ultimately bears the real tax burden. Thus, according to neoclassical public
economic theory,the economic incidence of a tax depends solely on the relative elasticity of supply and demand; that
is, the more inelastic one bears a greater burden. In other words, buyers will bear more of the tax burden if demand
schedule is more inelastic than supply and vice versa. Nevertheless, there is a growing literature(see, e.g., Biswas, Wil-
son, & Licata, 1993; Chetty et al., 2009; DellaVigna, 2009; Krishna, Briesch, Lehmann, & Yuan,2002; Slemrod, & Bakija,
2008), showing that other issues, such as behavioral and institutional factors, might affect tax incidence. In this sense,
Cox,Rider, and Sen (2017) investigated the influence of market institutions on tax incidence. Due to the coexistence of
many types of markets, each with different properties and mechanisms for the determination of price and quantities
traded between sellers and buyers, it is plausible to suppose that different market configurationsmight lead to differ-
ent incidence results. Cox et al. (2017) addressed two important research questions: Is tax incidence independent of
the assignment of the liability to pay tax in experimental markets? Is tax incidence independent of the marketinsti-
tution in experimental markets? Comparing a double-auction (DA) institution with a posted-offer market,1Coxet al.
1In experimental DA marketsbuyers and sellers are free to declare a price quote for one unit of the fictitious commodity within certain time constraints.
Each exchangecovers a single unit of commodity and is realized when one of the parties accepts the price quote proposed by the other party. In posted-offer
markets the seller publishes the prices of goods, possibly limiting the amount for sale and the buyer decides to buy this good on the basis of a comparison
betweenthe prices published by different sellers.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT