Exclusive licenses of patent and plant breeders’ rights under EEC law after Maize Seed

DOI10.1177/0003603X8302800305
Published date01 September 1983
Date01 September 1983
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Fall 1983
Exclusive licenses
of
patent
and plant breeders' rights
under EEC law after Maize Seed
BY VALENTINE KORAH*
I.
Introduction
699
The problems associated with the grant
of
exclusive licenses in
Europe differ greatly from those in the United States. The
differences arise in part from the lack
of
market integration in
Europe. The European Communities have not achieved a federa-
tion. When the Sherman Act was passed, the United States was
far more integrated than Europe was in 1958 or even in 1983.
National laws differ. Patents and other intellectual property
rights in Europe, unlike those in the United States, cover only a
single member state (except for the Benelux trademark and
registered designs, which cover three).
For
nearly two decades the
institutions
of
the European Communities have been cutting
down those elements
of
intellectual property rights that they
think might be used to delay the integration
of
the common
market.
In 1962, the Commission announced its view'that a patent
license limited to a part
of
the territory for which a patent was
Reader in English Law, University College, London; Barrister.
1J.O. 24 Dec. 1962, 139/2922, colloquially known as "the Christ-
mas Message."
©1984by Federal Legal Publications. Inc.
700 The antitrust bulletin
granted did
not
infringe article
85,2
since it was the
patent
and
not
collusion
that
restrained sales elsewhere. This was widely read as
permitting licenses limited to the area protected by a national
patent, so
that
the holder
of
counterpart patents in several
member states could divide the common market by assigning or
granting exclusive licenses under his patent rights in different
member states to different persons,' retaining the rights in a third
area
himself. Alternatively, the owner could discriminate by
invoking the
patent
rights in
the
higher-price areas to restrain the
import
or marketing
of
goods
that
had
been sold at lower prices
in other member states. The law
of
several member states pro-
vides
that
a
patent
is exhausted by a sale within the state made or
authorized by
the
holder, so
that
once the patentee or his licensee
has sold the protected article, he cannot use his
patent
rights to
restrain subsequent sales.
It
is thought
that
no
patent
law,
however, is similarly limited when the protected goods
had
been
first sold
abroad.'
The Commission also stated in the notice
of
1962
that
exclusivity was not contrary to article 85(1), since it
2Art.
85(1)
prohibits as incompatible with the common market
collusion between firms that may affect trade between member states
and has as its object or effect the prevention, restriction, or distortion
of competition within the common market. Paragraph (3) provides for
exemptions that can be
given
only by the Commission of the European
Communities, and paragraph (2) provides that agreements that infringe
the article shall be automatically void.
3The notice was expressed not to apply to "multiple parallel
licenses," so there were limits to the device, but two licenses are
probably not multiple. Contrast the
view
later adopted by the Commis-
sion, in the text accompany note 23 infra.
4The position differs for different kinds of right. International
exhaustion is not unusual in the case of trademarks. The U.K. does not
have a doctrine of exhaustion
exactly,
but there is an implied
license
to a
licensee
or purchaser to sell a protected article. See Revlon v. Cripps &
Lee,
[1980]
Fleet St. Reports 85, in relation to marks, and Betts v.
Willmott,
[1871]
L.R. 6, ch. 239, in relation to patents. Of course,
subject to art. 85, the implied license may be expressly restricted. See
also
w'R.
CORNISH,
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY: PATENTS, COPYRIGHT,
TRADE
MARKS
AND
ALLIED
RIGHTS
199
(1981).
Maize Seed 701
would seldom affect trade between member states. Both views
were, however, modified in the light
of
the case law of the Court
of
Justice
of
the European Communities, hereafter referred to as
the
"Court"
or the "Community Court."
In Consten and Grundig v. Commission? the Court held that
although national industrial and commercial property rights are
guaranteed by article 222
of
the
Treaty,"
their exercise is limited by
the application
of
other provisions in the Treaty. The existence
of
a right may be defined as the sum of the ways in which it may be
exercised. So the distinction between its existence and exercise
cannot be drawn by logical analysis,' but only by balancing the
relative importance
of
the functions served by the intellectual
property right and the integration of the market. Consequently,
the distinction does not lead to clear predictions and the Court
gave itself a very free hand to decide the extent to which
intellectual property rights should be cut down to facilitate the
integration
of
the common market (recognizing that in 1966 the
market's legislative body had ceased to function owing to the
French boycott
of
the Council
of
Ministers). In Consten and
Grundig v. Commission, the Court decided that the absolute
territorial protection conferred by Grundig on its exclusive dis-
tributor in France did infringe article 85(1),8 and that the Com-
5(56 and 58/64),
[1966)
E.C.R. 299;
[1966)
C.M.L.R. 418;
C.M.R. para. 8046.
6"This Treaty shall in no way prejudice the rules in Member States
governing the system
of
property ownership."
7On quick reading, the Court's judgments appear to be based on
logical analysis, but it rarely states why one objective is more important
than another.
It
tends to assert its conclusions at key points in the
judgment.
8Cited in note 5 supra. At p. 342 of the E.C.R., the Court stated
that an agreement tending to restrict intrabrand competition should not
escape the prohibition of art. 85(1) merely because it might increase
interbrand competition, but went on to add that there is no need to take
account
of
the concrete effects of an agreement once it is clear that its
object is to restrict competition. "Object" is a double concept. The

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT