Exchange rate volatility and Japan–U.S. commodity trade: An asymmetry analysis

Published date01 November 2019
AuthorHuseyin Karamelikli,Mohsen Bahmani‐Oskooee
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12856
Date01 November 2019
World Econ. 2019;42:3287–3318. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec
|
3287
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Received: 19 November 2018
|
Revised: 13 May 2019
|
Accepted: 8 August 2019
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12856
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Exchange rate volatility and Japan–U.S. commodity
trade: An asymmetry analysis
MohsenBahmani‐Oskooee1*
|
HuseyinKaramelikli2
1Department of Economics,The Center for Research on International Economics,The University of Wisconsin‐Milwaukee.
Milwaukee, WI, USA
2Department of Economics,Karabuk University, Karabuk, Turkey
KEYWORDS
asymmetry, commodity trade, exchange rate volatility, Japan, nonlinear ARDL, US
1
|
INTRODUCTION
When the international monetary system changed from a fixed to a relatively flexible exchange rate
system, many argued that the risk introduced by flexible rates could hurt the trade flows. Others ar-
gued to the contrary. Indeed, theoreticians developed theories that showed that exchange rate volatility
could have negative or positive effects on trade flows, depending on the degree of a trader's tolerance
to risk. While risk averse traders will trade less, risk tolerance traders will trade more.1 Indeed, the
empirical research reviewed by Bahmani‐Oskooee and Hegerty (2007) supports both views, regard-
less of the aggregation level of trade data. Trade data have been used between one country and the rest
of the world, between two countries at the aggregate bilateral level and between two countries at the
bilateral level but disaggregated by commodity (or industry).
As shown by the above review article, the literature is huge and each country today should be
considered and reviewed separately and our country of concern, Japan, is no exception. Bahmani‐
Oskooee and Ltaifa (1992) is a cross‐sectional study that found the negative impact of exchange rate
volatility on the exports of 86 countries that included Japan. Similar adverse effects were also reported
by Sauer and Bohara (2001) who relied upon a panel model using data from 91 countries over the
period 1973–93. Both studies suffer from aggregation bias since what is true about one cross‐sec-
tional unit may not be true for another unit. Indeed, when Sauer and Bohara (2001) estimated their
panel model using data from only 22 developed countries (DCs), the significantly negative effect of
exchange rate volatility disappeared. However, the panel model estimated for 22 DCs also suffers from
1 For a theoretical derivation of the link between trade flows and a measure of exchange rate volatility see Peree and Steinherr
(1989) and for arguments on the positive or negative effects of exchange rate volatility see De Grauwe (1988).
*Valuable comments of two anonymous referees and those of the associate editor are greatly appreciated. Remaining errors,
however, are our own.
3288
|
BAHMANI‐OSKOOEE ANd KARAMELIKLI
aggregation bias. The lack of a significant link between the exchange rate volatility and exports of 22
DCs could be due to an insignificant link between the two variables in most countries in the panel but
not in Japan. Of course, this hypothesis could be tested by estimating a time‐series model that draws
data only from Japan to which we turn to next.
Time‐series studies pertaining to Japan could be divided into three categories. The first in-
cludes those who have used Japan's trade flows with the rest of the world and mostly found the
significantly negative impact of exchange rate volatility on Japanese trade flows. The list in-
cludes Kenen and Rodrik (1986), Peree and Steinherr (1989), Asseery and Peel (1991), Qian
and Varangis (1994), Arize (1995), Arize and Shwiff (1998) and Poon, Choong, and Habibullah
(2005). Suspecting that these studies suffer from another aggregation bias, the second group has
used trade data at the bilateral level between Japan and another trading partner and have found
mixed results. While in the trade between Japan and the US. Aristotelous (2001) and Cushman
(1983) found negative effects of exchange rate volatility, De Vita and Abbott (2004) found posi-
tive effects. Cushman (1988) also found negative effects of exchange rate volatility on the export
volume of UK to Japan.
The bilateral studies do suffer from another aggregation bias in that the response of one industry
to exchange rate volatility could be different than the response of another industry. Thus, the third
group disaggregate trade flows between Japan and another partner by commodity. Maskus (1986)
considered US exports of 1‐digit SITC categories to Japan and found adverse effects of exchange
rate volatility. However, when Lee (1999) considered US imports of manufactured goods from
Japan, he found no significant effects. Bahmani‐Oskooee and Hegerty (2008) is the most compre-
hensive study that considers the response of trade flows of 117 industries that trade between Japan
and the U.S. They found that while in the short run many industries are affected by real yen–dollar
rate volatility, in the long‐run 25 Japanese export industries are affected negatively and 20 are af-
fected positively. As for the Japanese importing industries, 13 industries are affected negatively and
22 industries are affected positively. Most industries’ trade is unaffected by the volatility of real
yen–dollar rate.2 Could the lack of significant long‐run effects of yen–dollar volatility in most in-
dustries be due to assuming a linear adjustment of exchange rate volatility? Could we discover more
significant results if we introduce nonlinear adjustment of the volatility? Since using nonlinear
models amounts to testing for asymmetric response of trade flows to exchange rate volatility, we can
also ask whether trade flows respond to volatility changes in an asymmetric manner. Indeed,
Bahmani‐Oskooee and Aftab (2017) have argued and demonstrated that due to changes in traders
expectations and information, their reaction to a decrease in volatility could be different than their
reaction to an increase in volatility.
Therefore, our main purpose in this paper was to consider industry‐level trade flows between Japan
and the US and investigate asymmetric response of exports and imports of 57 industries to a measure
of exchange rate volatility. As will be shown, when increased volatilities are separated from decreased
volatilities, a relatively more significant link between trade flows and exchange rate volatility is dis-
covered. To demonstrate this, we outline the models and explain the methods in Section 2. We then
report the empirical results in Section 3 that is followed by a summary in Section 4. Definition of
variables and sources of data are cited in the Appendix.
2 Following the same line of research and methods as Bahmani‐Oskooee and Hegerty (2008), Baek (2013) investigates the
response of trade flows of only 10 single‐digit industries that trade between Japan and Korea. The findings are similar to
those of Bahmani‐Oskooee and Hegerty (2008) in that only in one Japanese importing industry (i.e., manufactured goods)
and two Japanese exporting industries (i.e., chemical and related products, and machinery and transport equipment) exchange
rate volatility had significantly negative long‐run effects.
|
3289
BAHMANI‐OSKOOEE ANd KARAMELIKLI
2
|
THE MODELS AND METHODS
A common practice by all previous studies is to adopt an export and an import demand model in which
a measure of exchange rate volatility in addition to the real exchange rate itself as well as a scale vari-
able are the main determinants of export and import demands.3 As such, we begin with the following
long‐run specifications:
In (1), it is assumed that Japanese real export of commodity i,
XJP
i
, depends on the level of in-
come or economic activity in the US, YUS , the real industry i‐specific yen–dollar rate, REXi, and the
GARCH‐based measure of volatility of REXi , denoted by Vi . Using industry‐specific real exchange
rate and industry‐specific real exchange rate volatility is another point of departure from all previous
studies which must be attributed to the availability of industry‐specific prices in Japan and the U.S.
As for the expected estimates of the coefficients, if economic growth in the US is to boost Japanese
exports, an estimate of α 1 is expected to be positive and if a real depreciation of the yen against the
US dollar, defined by a decline in the real exchange rate (Appendix) is to also boost Japanese export
of commodity i, an estimate of α 2 is expected to be negative. Finally, since exchange rate volatility
could have negative or positive effects on exports, an estimate of α 3 could be negative or positive.
Following the same line of argument above, Equation (2) identifies the main determinants of the
Japanese import demand for commodity i,
MJP
i
. Following previous literature, Japanese own income
or economic activity denoted by YJP, the real bilateral exchange rate specific to industry i, REXi, and
volatility of the exchange rate are assumed to be the main determinants. Once again, we expect an
estimate of β1 to be positive, and if yen depreciation is to discourage Japanese imports, we expect an
estimate of β2 also to be positive. Finally, an estimate of β3 could be negative or positive.
If we were only interested in long‐run coefficient estimates, we would estimate only Equations
(1) and (2). However, to learn about the short‐run effects, we need to rewrite (1) and (2) in error‐cor-
rection formats. In order to obtain short‐run and long‐run estimates in one step, we adopt Pesaran's,
Shin, and Smith (2001) ARDL bounds testing approach and rely upon the following error‐correction
models:
Once (3) and (4) are estimated by OLS, coefficient estimates attached to first‐differenced variables
signify short‐run effects and estimates of θ1θ3 normalised on θ0 in (3) and
𝜌1𝜌3
normalised on
𝜌0
in
3 This section closely follows Bahmani‐Oskooee and Aftab (2017).
(1)
ln
X
JP
i,t
=𝛼
o
+𝛼1lnY
US
t
+𝛼2lnREX
i
,
t
+𝛼3lnV
i
,
t
+𝜀
t.
(2)
ln
M
JP
i,t
=𝛽o+𝛽1lnY
JP
t
+𝛽2lnREXi,t+𝛽3lnVi,t+𝜇t
.
(3)
Δ
ln XJP
i,t=a1+
n1
j=1
a2jΔln XJP
i,tj+
n2
j=0
a3jΔln YUS
tj+
n3
j=0
a4jΔln REXi,tj+
n4
j=0
a5jΔln Vi,t
j
+𝜃
0
ln XJP
i,t1
+𝜃
1
ln YUS
t1
+𝜃
2
ln REX
i,t1
+𝜃
3
ln V
i,t1
+𝜀
t
.
(4)
ln MJP
i,t=b1+
j=1
b2jΔln MJP
i,tj+
j=0
b3jΔln YJP
tj+
j=0
b4jΔln REXi,tj+
j=0
b5jΔln Vi,t
+𝜌0ln MJP
+𝜌1ln YJP
+𝜌2ln REXi,t1+𝜌3ln Vi,t1+𝜀t.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT