Evolutionary Models of Legal Change and the Albrecht Rule

DOI10.1177/0003603X8703200406
Published date01 December 1987
AuthorRoger D. Blair,Carolyn D. Schafer
Date01 December 1987
Subject MatterEconomic
The Antitrust Bulletin/Winter 1987
Evolutionary models
of
legal change
and the Albrecht rule
BY ROGER D. BLAIR and CAROLYN D. SCHAFER*
I.
Introduction
989
A fascinating series
of
articles has improved our understanding
of
the common law's evolutionary process.' When legal rules are
economically inefficient, they impose deadweight losses upon one
Professor
of
Economics and Research Associate, respectively,
University
of
Florida, Gainesville, Florida.
AUTHORS' NOTE: The authors appreciatethe financial support provided
by the Department
of
Economics and the Public Policy Research Center
at the University
of
Florida. The views expressed are solely those
of
the
authors. Helpful comments and encouragement were provided by
Malcolm Burns, Herbert Hovenkamp, and some anonymous referees.
I The seminal piece was provided by Rubin, Why Is the Common
Law Efficient?, 6
JOURNAL
OF
LEGAL
STUDIES
51 (1977); which was re-
fined and extended by Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selec-
tion
of
Efficient Rules, 6
JOURNAL
OF
LEGAL
STUDIES
65 (1977);
Goodman,
An
Economic Theory
of
the Evolution
of
the Common Law,
7
JOURNAL
OF
LEGAL
STUDIES
393 (1978); Priest, Selective Characteristics
of
Litigation, 9
JOURNAL
OF
LEGAL
STUDIES
399 (1980); Blume &Rubin-
feld, The Dynamics
of
the Legal Process, 11
JOURNAL
OF
LEGAL
STUDIES
405 (1982); Priest &Klein, The Selection
of
Disputes
for
Litigation, 13
JOURNAL
OF
LEGAL
STUDIES
1 (1984); Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the
Law: On the Evolution
of
Legal Precedent and Rules, 15
JOURNAL
OF
LEGAL
STUDIES
227 (1986).
©1988 by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
990 The antitrust bulletin
of
the parties to a dispute. As a result, the value
of
an inefficient
rule to its beneficiary is less than the loss to the disadvantaged
party. This means that the disadvantaged party has more to gain
than the beneficiary has to lose by a change to an efficient rule.
If
the litigants have a continuing interest in precedent, they will
represent all future interests in the legal rule in question.' Under
these circumstances, there will be an incentive for the inefficient
rule to be litigated until precedent is changed and an efficient rule
emerges.
Although our antitrust law is based upon statutes (primarily
the Sherman Act
of
1890 and the Clayton Act
of
1914), the
statutory language does not drive the results. These statutes
contain vague prohibitions that require judicial interpretation in
the common-law tradition. One may argue, as we do in the next
section, that antitrust is simply a federal common law based upon
astatutory foundation. In his remarkable survey
of
antitrust,
Robert Bork found inefficient rules in nearly every area
of
the
law.' Aparticularly egregious example is provided by the eco-
nomically inefficient Albrecht rule prohibiting the imposition
of
maximum resale prices.' In spite
of
its inefficiency, we find that
the Albrecht rule is not litigated very often. We examine this rule
in an evolutionary context and offer some explanations for the
absence of litigation.
2 This issue is discussed more fully by Rubin, supra note 1.
3 R.
BORK,
THE
ANTITRUST
PARADOX:
A
POLICY
AT
WAR
WITH
ITSELF
(1978).
4 This rule was enunciated in Albrecht v. Herald Co., 390 U.S. 145
(1968). The Albrecht rule has been examined in some detail and found
wanting. See, e.g., Blair &Kaserman, The Albrecht Rule and Consumer
Welfare:
An
Economic Analysis, 33
UNIVERSITY
OF
FLORIDA
LAW
REVIEW
461 (1981); Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48
UNIVERSITY
OF
CHI-
CAGO
LAW
REVIEW
886 (1981); Blair &Fesmire, Maximum Price Fixing
and the Goals
of
Antitrust, 37
SYRACUSE
LAW
REVIEW
43 (1986).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT