Ethical Debates, Economic Theories, and Real-World Impacts

AuthorDeborah A. Geier
Pages61-107
Chapter 3: Ethical Debates,
Economic Theories, and Real-World Impacts
Chapters 1 and 2 explored the contours of two common types of “tax base” (what is taxed):
income and consumption. Part A. of this chapter will relate information regarding the adoption
and development of the income tax over time and its impact on the Federal budget and living
standards. Part B. will explore the norms, theories, and politics of taxation, which will draw on
some of the information conveyed in Part A. regarding economic trends over time. While the
material in Chapters 1 and 2 was chiefly descriptive, some of the material in this chapter comes
with a lot of baggage in the political arena. Thus, I want to say a word first about how we
sometimes approach material of this type.
We all have unique ways of looking at the world and making sense of it. We all begin our
decision-making processes and evaluations with certain models in our minds of how the world
works and should work, which have been ingrained by culture, education, family, religion, events,
and perhaps even our genes. These models shape how we perceive the world. Thus, two different
people looking at precisely the same situation can have very different perceptions about what the
most consequential facts are. Indeed, cognitive psychologists have identified the so-called
confirmation bias as one of the most potent cognitive biases that we all share.
Although he is a cognitive psychologist and not an economist, Daniel Kahnman won the 2002
Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel (commonly referred
to as the Nobel Prize in Economics) in recognition of the contributions that he and the late Amos
Tversky made in helping us to better understand how thought patterns and behavior differ in
predictable ways from the “rational man” assumptions that economists often typically build into
their economic models. Their work (and the work of others) led to the burgeoning field of
“behavioral economics,” which seeks to study these behaviors in a systematic way.
Behavioral economists and cognitive psychologists have identified numerous “cognitive
biases” that we, as humans, all share. The confirmation bias mentioned above is the tendency to
search for or interpret information in a way that confirms one’s preconceptions.
Disconfirmation bias,” as one would expect, is the opposite: the tendency for people to dismiss
or avoid information which contradicts their prior beliefs.
The technology revolution, with the introduction first of cable television and then the internet,
has created niches that make it ever easier to indulge in (or exploit) the confirmation bias. In the
dark ages of my childhood, with only three nationally broadcast news stations with a high number
of homes watching each evening, the three national news programs had to steer a path that appealed
broadly and thus could not cater in an obvious way to the extreme left or right of the political
spectrum. In addition, prior to 1987 the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) required,
under the so-called fairness doctrine, that radio and television broadcasters using the public air
waves must present multiple viewpoints on contentious public debates. The FCC members
appointed by President Ronald Reagan abolished the fairness doctrine in 1987. These events have
combined to allow us to subdivide ourselves into information niches in which we hear only echoes
of our prior beliefs, reinforcing them even further, turbo-charging the confirmation bias.
Another cognitive bias is the “bias blind spot,” or the tendency to see oneself as less biased
than other people, or to be able to identify more cognitive biases in others than in oneself.
Chapter 3 Ethical Debates, Economic Theories, Real-World Impacts Chapter 3
-62-
Particularly in my role as a teacher, I always try to remain sensitive to this bias in myself.
Other cognitive biases that can have an impact on taxation include the endowment effect (or
divestiture aversion), which is the tendency to ascribe more value to items or a position merely
because we own them. Studies show that people who are given, say, a coffee mug demand more
in cash to give up the mug than they would be willing to pay to purchase the item. This effect
contributes to the cognitive bias known as loss aversion, under which people strongly prefer
avoiding losses to acquiring gains. These biases can result in behavior that is inconsistent with
the “rational man” assumptions made by some economists in modeling predictions of anticipated
behavior changes in connection with a proposed change in law, including tax law.
Several other cognitive biases combine to make us sometimes make judgments based on a
personally known anecdote or widely reported example in the press of one case or incident, while
downplaying larger pools of evidence or data that contradict the individual anecdote. These include
the base rate neglect or base rate fallacy, or the tendency to base judgments on specifics,
ignoring general statistical information; the availability heuristic, or estimating what is more
likely by what is more available in memory, which is biased toward vivid, unusual, or
emotionally charged examples; and the anchoring effect, or the tendency to rely too heavily,
or “anchor,” on a past reference or on one trait or piece of information when making
decisions (also called “insufficient adjustment”). As an example of this cognitive bias in the tax
policy setting, the popular press widely reported that the French actor Gerard Depardieu obtained
a Russian passport after the former French President recommended temporarily raising (for two
years) the top marginal income tax rate from 41% to 75% on income exceeding €1 million. This
vivid example of fleeing a country (or a state in the U.S.) in response to an increase in the top tax
rate can cause a reader to believe that this response is a common one, a belief that can affect the
analysis of the policy issue, but broader empirical data is not consistent with this assumption.1
As an aside, those looking for good empirical data can often find it by looking at material
published by the Congressional Budget Office, the Tax Policy Center (a joint undertaking between
the Urban Institute and the Brookings Institution), the Census Bureau, the IRS Statistics of Income
Division, and the Joint Committee on Taxation, a committee nominally made up of the members
of the House Ways & Means Committee and the Senate Finance Committee, but whose work is
done by its professional staff consisting of economists and lawyers charged with, among other
duties, scoring tax bills and doing studies mandated by Congress. Information pertaining to the
experience of other nations can often be found in data compiled by the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD).
A. The development of the income tax and
how taxes affect the Federal budget and living standards
Under the Articles of Confederation that preceded the Constitution, the Federal government
had no power to tax individuals, states, or business entities directly. Rather, the Federal
government could only send a “requisition” to each state to collect a stated amount to turn over to
the Federal government, and the states were left to decide for themselves how to fulfill the
requisition. As you might expect, states often failed to comply, and the very survival of the new
1 See, e.g., James B. Stewart, The Myth of the Rich Who Flee from Taxes, at
www.nytimes.com/2013/02/16/business/high-taxes-are-not-a-prime-reason-for-relocation-studies-say.html.
Chapter 3 Ethical Debates, Economic Theories, Real-World Impacts Chapter 3
-63-
country was threatened, as the Federal government needed revenue to retire the Revolutionary War
debt, maintain the military and courts, etc. Thus, a primary reason for calling a Constitutional
Convention to replace the Articles of Confederation was the need to provide the Federal
government with the power to tax citizens and residents directly, without going through the states.
“For a generation that had fought a war with England about taxation, however, it was equally
important that any taxing power be constrained.”2 Thus, both a “uniformity” and “apportionment”
requirement were included with respect to the Federal taxing power.
Under Article 1, § 8, clause 1, of the Constitution, Congress is granted power to “lay and collect
Taxes, Duties, Imposts, and Excises” on individuals, entities, transactions, etc., without going
through the states, but these levies must “be uniform throughout the United States.” This
“uniformity” requirement prevents express discrimination among the states. Thus, for example, if
Congress enacted an excise tax tomorrow on the extraction of each barrel of oil from the ground,
it could not impose that tax at a rate of, say, 10% for oil found in Texas but 20% for oil found in
Alaska without violating the uniformity clause. The fact that oil is distributed unevenly among the
states, however, which means that entities and individuals in Texas and Alaska would pay much
more of this hypothetical oil excise tax than would residents in Tennessee or Vermont, would not
violate the uniformity clause.
Article 1, § 9, clause 4, requires that all “direct” taxes, including any “capitation” tax (or per-
person head tax), be apportioned among the states according to population. Taxes that are not
“direct” taxes are not subject to the apportionment requirement. Though the Constitution does not
use the term, taxes that do not qualify as direct have come to be known as “indirect” taxes. The
distinction between a direct and indirect tax is somewhat cloudy (more below), but taxes imposed
on individuals for merely existing (a capitation tax) or merely owning property (such as real estate)
have been held to be direct taxes, while taxes imposed only on a transaction, such as the
hypothetical oil excise tax described above or a retail sales tax imposed on the purchase of
consumer items, have been held to be indirect.
Direct taxes were thought to have greater potential for abuse in that they were imposed merely
for existing or owning real estate and thus could not easily be escaped by citizens and residents.
Excise and sales taxes, in contrast, were relatively noncontroversial forms of taxation becaus e they
could be avoided simply by choosing not to extract the oil (in the hypothetical example provided
above) or choosing not to purchase the consumer item. As Alexander Hamilton wrote in Federalist
21:
It is a signal advantage of taxes on articles of consumption that they contain in their
own nature a security against excess. They prescribe their own limit; which cannot
be exceeded without defeating the end proposed, that is, an extension of the
revenue. When applied to this object, the saying is as just as it is witty, that, “in
political arithmetic, two and two do not always make four.” If duties are too high,
they lessen the consumption; the collection is eluded; and the product to the treasury
is not so great as when they are confined within proper and moderate bounds. This
forms a complete barrier against any material oppression of the citizens by taxes of
this class, and is itself a natural limitation of the power of imposing them.
To illustrate how the apportionment requirement might work, assume that Congress decided
2 ERIK M. JENSEN, THE TAXING POWER: A REFERENCE GUIDE TO THE UNITED STATES CONSTITUTION 17 (2005).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT