Equity Option Implied Probability of Default and Equity Recovery Rate

Published date01 June 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.21823
Date01 June 2017
AuthorBo Young Chang,Greg Orosi
Equity Option Implied Probability of
Default and Equity Recovery Rate
Bo Young Chang and Greg Orosi*
There is a close link between prices of equity options and the default probability of a firm.
We show that in the presence of positive expected equity recovery, standard methods that
assume zero equity recovery at default misestimate the option-implied default probability. We
introduce a simple method to detect stocks with positive expected equity recovery by examining
option prices and propose a method to extract the default probability from option prices that
allows for positive equity recovery. We demonstrate possible applications of our methodology
with examples that include financial institutions in the United States during the 2007–09
subprime crisis. ©2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 37:599–613, 2017
1. INTRODUCTION
There is a long line of literature linking option pricing models with the probability of default
of a firm, following the seminal work by Merton (1974). Most of the studies in this literature
(e.g., Bayraktar & Yang, 2011; Carr & Linetsky, 2006; Carr & Madan, 2010; Carr & Wu,
2009; and Linetsky, 2006) assume that there is no residual asset left to pay equity investors
in the event of a firm’s default. That is, the stock price goes to zero when a default occurs.
In most cases, the assumption of zero equity recovery at default is valid. However, in some
instances, there is significant residual value to equity investors even after a firm defaults.
To file for bankruptcy, a company is supposed to be insolvent, with debts exceeding
assets. As debt holders must be paid back before shareholders, typically firms do not have
residual funds to pay equity holders. However, some firms end up in Chapter 11 bankruptcy,
not because they are insolvent, but because they cannot get new loans or refinance existing
debt. Furthermore, for various strategic reasons, both equity holders and debt holders have
incentives to induce bankruptcy well before the equity value reaches zero.1
Bo Young Chang is at the Bank of Canada, 234 Laurie Ave. West, Ottawa, Ontario, Canada. Greg Orosi
is the Associate Professor at Department of Mathematics and Statistics, American University of Sharjah,
Sharjah, UAE. Wethank Robert Webb (Editor), the anonymous referee, Kwangil Bae, Narayan Bulusu, Peter
Christoffersen, Bruno Feunou, Jean-S´
ebastien Fontaine, Jos´
e Da Fonseca, Jun Yang, as well as participants at
the Bank of Canada Fellowship Learning Exchange, Quantitative Methods in Finance Conference, Auckland
Centre for Financial Research Derivative Markets Conference, and the Annual Conference of the Asia-Pacific
Association of Derivatives for helpful comments and suggestions.
JEL Classification: G13
*Correspondence author,Department of Mathematics and Statistics, American University of Sharjah, Office: Nab
254, P.O.Box 26666, Sharjah, UAE, Tel: 971-6-515-2332, Fax: 971-6-515-2950, e-mail: gorosi@aus.edu.
Received December 2015; Accepted September 2016
1See Broadie, Chernov,and Sundaresan (2007); Davydenko (2012); Fan and Sundaresan (2000); Hackbarth, Hen-
nessy, and Leland (2007); Leland (1994); and Leland and Toft (1996)
The Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 37, No.6, 599–613 (2017)
©2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Published online 9 November 2016 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com).
DOI: 10.1002/fut.21823

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT