Entrepreneurial risk aversion, net worth effects and real fluctuations

Published date01 November 2013
AuthorCristian Pardo
Date01 November 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2013.05.007
Entrepreneurial risk aversion, net worth effects and real uctuations
Cristian Pardo
Department of Economics, Saint Joseph's University, 5600 City Avenue, Philadelphia, PA 19131, United States
abstractarticle info
Article history:
Received 4 August 2012
Received in revised form 21 May 2013
Accepted 29 May 2013
Available online 10 June 2013
JEL classication:
D82
E32
Keywords:
Entrepreneurial risk aversion
Asymmetric and private information
Contracts
Business cycles
This paper examines the combined effect of asymmetric information and private entrepreneurial risk aver-
sion on investment decisions. The standard optimal debt contract becomes modied by the introduction of
insurance and a risk premium that entrepreneurs demand due to the uncertainty of their investment returns:
the private equity premium. In general equilibrium, the private equity premium may become a mechanism
that magnies the effects of shocks. A structural estimation of the model's parameters using Chilean and
U.S. data shows that the entrepreneurial risk aversion assumption has more empirical relevance in an econ-
omy where smaller privately-held businesses are relatively more prevalent than where the corporate sector
predominates, like the U.S.
© 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
The fact that emerging markets tend to present stronger output
responses to shocks than industrialized economies has been widely
studied in the literature. Backus and Kehoe (1992)and Prasad, Agen or,
and McDermott (1999),tonameafew,provideempiricalevidence
supporting such an assertion. More often than not, differences in
observed average GDP volatility among countries are attributed to vari-
ations in the levels of development of their nancial markets. In some
economies, however, the entrepreneurial sector can be a signicant
source of volatility as well.
Table C.1, which presents the volatility of entrepreneurial activity
across countries as measured by the standard deviation of the Total
Entrepreneurial Activity index (TEA),
1
shows that the volatility of
entrepreneurial activity is on average more than 2.5 times larger in
developing countries than in developed ones. An illustrative example
is the Chilean case. While it boasts one of the most robust nancial
systems in its region, its economy still reacted strongly to the effects
of the Asian crisis of the late 1990s. A reason often cited for the
observed response was that the entrepreneurial sector in Chile moved
quickly from an early-to-mid 1990's boom euphoria to a deepdepres-
sion in the followingyears.
While numerous models have attempted to explain business cycle
uctuations as a result of nancial imperfections, few incorporate the
behavior of the entrepreneurial sector as a direct mechanism behind
business cycles volatility. Fig. C.1 provides preliminary evidence of a
positive simple direct correlation between the total entrepreneurial
activity volatility and output growth volatility, as measured by the
standard deviations of the TEA index and per capita real GDP growth
for 31 countries, respectively.
This paper deals with the role of the private entrepreneurial sector
as an additional source of business cycle volatility. As in Bernanke and
Gertler (1989), capital-producing entrepreneurs nance their invest-
ments by engaging in debt contracts with lenders, a relationship that
is subject to standard frictions such as asymmetric information prob-
lems. In addition, this paper introduces a second friction in this model
that results from private entrepreneurial risk aversion.
For simplicity, entrepreneurs are commonly modeledas risk-neutral
agents. As Gale andHellwig (1985) point out that, risk neutrality is not
an unreasonable assumption to makein the case of investorssince it can
be justied as a consequence of risk-pooling.However,theauthorsalso
claim that risk neutrality makes lesssense in the case of entrepreneurs
and indeed is merely a simplifyingassumptionwhich shouldbe relaxed
if possible.That is, as entrepreneurs are less likely to have access to
complete risk-pooling for their idiosyncratic risks, risk aversion is argu-
ablya more realisticassumption inmodeling theirinvestment decisions.
In fact, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen (2002) show that private
entrepreneurs tend to invest in privately-owned businesses that are typ-
icallysmall and ownedby few or just oneentrepreneur.The authors also
nd that private entrepreneurs usually invest at least 50% of their assets
Review of Financial Economics 22 (2013) 158168
Tel.: +1 610 660 1526; fax: +1 610 660 3379.
E-mail address: cpardo@sju.edu.
1
This index, developed by the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM), measures
the relative amount of nascent entrepreneurs and business owners of young rms for
75 countries from 2001 to the present (van Stel, Carree, & Thurik, 2005).
1058-3300/$ see front matter © 2013 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2013.05.007
Contents lists available at ScienceDirect
Review of Financial Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/rfe

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT