Enterprise Risk Management and the Cost of Capital

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12152
Published date01 March 2018
Date01 March 2018
© 2016 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol. 85, No. 1, 159–201 (2018).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12152
159
ENTERPRISE RISK MANAGEMENT AND THE COST OF
CAPITAL
Thomas R. Berry-St
olzle
Jianren Xu
ABSTRACT
Enterprise risk management (ERM) is a process that manages all risks in an
integrated, holistic fashion by controlling and coordinating any offsetting
risks across the enterprise. This research investigates whether the adoption
of the ERM approach affects firms’ cost of equity capital. We restrict our
analysis to the U.S. insurance industry to control for unobservable
differences in business models and risk exposures across industries. We
simultaneously model firms’ adoption of ERM and the effect of ERM on the
cost of capital. We find that ERM adoption significantly reduces firm’s cost of
capital. Our results suggest that cost of capital benefits are one answer to the
question how ERM can create value.
INTRODUCTION
Enterprise risk management (ERM) is a holistic approach to risk management.
Traditionally, corporations managed risks arising from their business units
separately in each unit. ERM improves on this traditional “silo”-based approach
by coordinating and controlling any offsetting risks across the enterprise. A number
of surveys document how firms implement ERM programs to achieve such synergies
between different risk management activities (see, e.g., Colquitt, Hoyt, and Lee, 1999;
Kleffner, Lee, and McGannon, 2003; Beasley, Clune, and Hermanson, 2005; Altuntas,
Berry-St
olzle, and Hoyt, 2011), a number of studies on firms’ decision to start an ERM
program provide evidence that firms adopt ERM for direct economic benefits (see,
e.g., Liebenberg and Hoyt, 2003; Pagach and Warr, 2011; Altuntas, Berry-St
olzle, and
Hoyt, 2012), and a limited number of studies provide evidence that ERM is associated
Thomas R. Berry-St
olzle is at the Henry B. Tippie College, University of Iowa, 108 John
Pappajohn Business Bldg, Iowa City, IA 52242–1994. He can be contacted via e-mail: thomas-
berry@uiowa.edu. Jianren Xu is at the Mihaylo College of Business and Economics, California
State University, Fullerton, 800 N. State College Blvd., Fullerton, CA 92831. He can be contacted
via e-mail: jrxu@fullerton.edu.
160 THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE
with improvements in firm performance and increases in firm value (see, e.g., Hoyt
and Liebenberg, 2011; Eckles, Hoyt, and Miller, 2014; Farrell and Gallagher, 2015;
Grace et al., 2015). While this prior literature argues that ERM can create value by
creating synergies between different risk management activities, increasing capital
efficiency, avoiding the underinvestment problem in financially constrained firms,
and by reducing the cost of external financing, there is a lack of empirical evidence
supporting these claims.
The goal of our research is to shed some light on the fundamental question of how
ERM can create value. We specifically focus on the relationship between ERM
adoption and firms’ cost of external financing, and investigate whether ERM adoption
is negatively associated with the cost of equity capital. Such a research design allows
us to evaluate whether cost of capital benefits are one mechanism for value creation by
the ERM approach.
There are multiple conceptual arguments why ERM adoption should reduce a firm’s
cost of capital. First, an ERM program improves the information available about a
firm’s risk profile, and this information can be shared with investors, reducing
information asymmetries and leading to a lower cost of capital (see, e.g., Easley and
O’Hara, 2004; Lambert, Leuz, and Verrecchia, 2007). Second, ERM decreases firms’
cost of capital through reducing firms’ systematic risk. Hann, Ogneva, and Ozbas
(2013) originally used this argument to explain why diversified firms benefit from a
lower cost of capital than their focused counterparts. When firms experience low cash
flows, they incur certain deadweight losses, for example, the loss of valuable
personnel. Such deadweight losses are more pronounced during economic down-
turns. In other words, these deadweight losses are at least partially countercyclical
and increase systematic risk. Hann, Ogneva, and Ozbas document that diversified
firms with less correlated segment cash flows have a lower cost of capital, supporting
the view that coinsurance reduces systematic risk. ERM improves on the traditional
risk management approach by its focus on understanding and managing correla-
tions and interaction of risk or, in other words, by its focus on managing the
coinsurance effect, thereby reducing systematic risk. Third, ERM adoption reduces
the probability that a firm needs expensive external financing (Froot, Scharfstein,
and Stein, 1993). In addition, ERM adoption can improve firms’ ratings, which are
used by outside investors as a signal of financial strength; Standard & Poor’s aswell as
other rating agencies explicitly evaluate firms’ ERM program as part of the rating
process.
To avoid possible spurious correlations cause d by unobservable diffe rences in
business models and risk exposures across industr ies, we restrict our analy sis to a
single industry, an ind ustry that is almost tai lor-made for an empiric al analysis
of ERM programs and their cost of capital implica tions: the U.S. insuran ce
industry. The insuranc e industry embraced the ERM approach, and a substantia l
fraction of insurers adop ted an ERM program, provid ing the necessary variat ion
for an empirical analysi s. In addition, the U.S . insurance industry is t he only
insurance industry wo rldwide with a substant ial number of publicly t raded stock
companies, providing t he necessary stock pric e data for cost of equity ca pital
calculations. Since insu rance companies hardly ever iss ue bonds, we can simply
ERM AND THE COST OF CAPITAL 161
focus on their cost of equity ca pital to approximate their weighted average or tot al
cost of capital.
1
Our cost of equity capital measure is based on the implied cost of capital approach
(see, e.g., Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan, 2001), which equates the firm’s market
value of equity with its discounted future cash flow estimates, and solves for the
required internal rate of return. We use an implied cost of capital measure because
such measures better explain variations in expected stock returns than realized stock
returns (see, e.g., Gebhardt, Lee, and Swaminathan, 2001; P
astor, Sinha, and
Swaminathan, 2008; Li, Ng, and Swaminathan, 2013). The main differences between
implied cost of capital measures are the valuation model used to describe future cash
flows and the growth assumptions in perpetuity. To ensure that our results are robust
to method choice, we calculate four different implied cost of capital measures and
take the average across those four measures. This average is the main cost of capital
measure used in our analysis.
2
Following the procedure suggested by Beasley, Pagach, and Warr (2008), Hoyt and
Liebenberg (2011), and Pagach and Warr (2011), we systematically search newswires
and other media, as well as financial reports, for evidence of ERM program adoption
by our sample insurance companies. We then use two procedures to test whether
ERM adoption is actually accompanied by a decrease in firms’ cost of capital. First,
we use an event study methodology and test for an abnormal reduction in the cost
of capital around the year of ERM adoption. Second, we explicitly model the
determinants of ERM adoption and estimate a two-equation treatment effects model
to assess the effect of ERM use on firms’ cost of capital. For ERM adopters, the ERM
indicator variable in this model is coded equal to 1 in the year of ERM adoption and all
following years; the variable is equal to 0 in the years prior to ERM adoption. For firms
that do not adopt ERM during our sample period, the ERM indicator is equal to 0 for
1
Insurance companies receive premium payments up front, invest the premium money in the
capital markets, and pay claims once they occur. If premiums are calculated properly and
investments are well managed, there is no need for additional liquidity. Capital has the
important function to serve as a buffer that can absorb higher than expected losses.
The insurance industry is a regulated industry and regulators monitor how much capital
insurance companies have on their balance sheet relative to the liabilities to policyholders.
There are regulatory capital requirements, and bonds do not count as capital. While the
average industrial firm issues capital as well as bonds and focuses on its weighted cost of
capital including the cost of debt to make investment decisions, for insurance companies, the
weighted cost of capital is basically equivalent to the cost of equity capital. All articles
measuring insurance companies’ cost of capital we are aware of only focus on the cost of equity
capital (see, e.g., Cummins and Phillips, 2005; Wen et al., 2008; Pottier and Xu, 2014). Cummins
and Phillips (2005) even break down the overall cost of capital of a firm to the individual
business lines, providing a methodology to use the cost of equity capital for financial decision
making within insurance companies.
2
The four implied cost of capital measures used in our analysis are Gebhardt, Lee, and
Swaminathan’s (2001) industry ROE method, Gordon and Gordon’s (1997) finite horizon
method, Gode and Mohanram’s (2003) economy-wide growth method, and Easton’s (2004)
price-earnings-growth ratio.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT