Endogenous formation of multiple social groups

Published date01 September 2020
AuthorNgoc M. Nguyen,Lionel Richefort,Thomas Vallée
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12442
Date01 September 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:13681390.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet1368
|
© 2020 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 4 December 2018
|
Accepted: 21 March 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12442
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Endogenous formation of multiple social
groups
Ngoc M. Nguyen |Lionel Richefort |Thomas Vallée
LEMNA, University of Nantes, Nantes,
France
Correspondence
Ngoc M. Nguyen, LEMNA, University of
Nantes, Nantes 44000, France.
Email: nguyenngocminh87@gmail.com
Abstract
This paper explores a model of group membership
formation in which agents decide to join or not
multiple social groups. The membership formation
process induces a bipartite graph structure with
social groups listed on one side and agents listed on
the other side. Among members of multiple social
groups, we consider two decisive types of agents: the
grand star and the mini star. The former type is
the unique agent in a society who participates in all
social groups. The latter type includes agents who
participate in more than one, but not all, social
groups such that every social group pair has one and
only one common member. We analyze the efficiency
and stability conditions of group membership
formation, and we establish sufficient conditions
under which a connected graph that contains either a
grand star or a set of mini stars becomes the unique
strongly efficient and stable graph.
1|INTRODUCTION
In modern societies, the potential physical or virtual connections between people naturally
create numerous social groups that, in turn, play an important role in people's lives. Primary
groups, such as family and friends, provide one of the most important elements of Maslow's
hierarchy of needs: the sense of belonging. However, these groups only partially satisfy
people's physiological and psychological needs. The unsatisfied needs can be fulfilled through
participation in secondary groups in college, at the office, or in other social environments
encountered in daily life.
Membership in a social group offers access to resources that are only shared among the
group's members. Moreover, a crucial feature of social groups is communication among
members to meet basic needs. This information exchange process allows members of a social
group to assist each other, enhance their individual capacities, and develop personality traits.
Additionally, to maintain their collective benefits, social groups should be considered as
representatives of all people in society (Richter & Hatch, 2013).
It should be noted that benefits from membership in social groups are not infinitive. Buchanan
(1965) characterized these benefits as excludable, congestible and divisible local public goods, and
proposed an efficient procedure for consuming these goods. Besides, if there exists a sufficient
number of social groups in society, agents can choose to participate in only some of them to
maximize their utility so that the benefits from memberships in social groups are (near) optimally
allocated (Tiebout, 1956). Wooders (1978) characterized the Tiebout equilibrium as a core
equivalence and developed a markettypeequilibrium for local public goods. Moreover, with the
presence of multiple memberships, the set of equilibrium outcomes is always reachable regardless
the sizes of social groups (Allouch & Wooders, 2008).Recentstudiescomparednetworksandlocal
public good when analyzing network formation mechanism (see, e.g., Haller, 2016).
In reality, agents must often pay participation costs to directly enjoy the collective benefits
provided by social groups. From the perspective of agents, however, these benefits can be
obtained both directly and indirectly. Consider a bipartite graph structure in which agents
choose to participate in two social groups, s
1
and
s
2
, as in Figure 1. If agent aiis a member of
social group s
1
, she obtains a direct benefit from her membership in s
1
. However, if aiis not a
member of s
1
, she may still obtain an indirect benefit from s
1
if she knows a member of s
1
.
More precisely, aimay obtain an indirect benefit from s
1
if she participates in another group,
s
2
, with a member, agent a
t
, who is also a member of s
1
. Thus, aiand a
t
know each other
through
s
2
. In other words, the connection between s
1
and
s
2
is through agent a
t
, and this
connection allows the members of
s
2
(including agent ai) to receive an indirect benefit from s
1
and vice versa. As a consequence, the decision of aito participate in s
1
depends on the values of
both the direct and indirect benefits that she can obtain from s
1
.
Studies on graph theory have demonstrated various applications of bipartite graphs. For
example, researchers have highlighted the bilateral bargaining process between traders and the
effect of exogenous graph structures on economic outcomes (CorominasBosch, 2004; Kranton
& Minehart, 2001; Wang & Watts, 2006). Other studies have focused on the structural properties
FIGURE 1 An example bipartite graph structure of two social groups
NGUYEN ET AL.
|
1369

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT